Article
Integration of Primary and Resale Platforms
Tianxin Zou and Baojun Jiang
Abstract
Consumers can buy concert tickets from primary platforms (e.g., Ticketmaster) or from consumer-to-consumer resale platforms
(e.g., StubHub). Recently, Ticketmaster has entered and been trying to control the resale market by prohibiting consumers from
reselling on competing resale platforms. Several states in the United States have passed or are discussing laws requiring tickets to
be transferrable on any resale sites, worrying that platform integration—Ticketmaster controlling both the primary and the resale
platforms—will increase ticket service fees and harm musicians and consumers. This article establishes a game-theoretic
framework and shows that the opposite can happen: platform integration can lower the service fees in both markets, alleviat-
ing double marginalization in the primary market and benefiting the musician and consumers. Moreover, with platform integration,
the presence of a small number of scalpers can counterintuitively reduce the ticket price and benefit the musicians and consumers.
In addition, platform competition in the resale market may harm consumers. This article further shows that these insights apply in
other markets (e.g. used goods, peer-to-peer product-sharing markets) and provides suggestive empirical support for the the-
oretical results.
Keywords
antitrust, channel coordination, consumer welfare, event ticket, platform, regulation, resale, secondary market
Online supplement: https://doi.org/10.1177/0022243720917352
In 2017, the U.S. concert-ticket industry reached over $3 bil-
lion in revenue, with more than 20 million consumers having
attended at least one concert.
1
Ticketmaster, with over 80% of
the U.S. market share, is the dominant primary platform for
concert ticke ts (Rob erts 2013). T icketmaster mainly profits
from the service fees paid by ticket buyers. For example, it
charged a $17.85 service fee for a $61 ticket of Justin Timber-
lake’s The Man of the Woods Tour at Madison Square Garden.
The peer-to-peer ticket resale market is also growing rapidly.
StubHub, with over 50% share of the U.S. ticket-resale market,
has seen a 30% growth rate in revenue in 2015 (Thomas 2016).
Over the past few years, Ticketmaster has expanded its
business from the primary market to the resale market. In
2008, it acquired TicketsNow, an online ticket resale platform,
for $265 million (Smith 2008). In 2013, Ticketmaster intro-
duced its own “Fan-to-Fan” resale system, Ticketmaster Resale
(formerly TMþ). Musicians can enroll in Ticketmaster Resale
to allow consumers to resell their tickets to other consumers on
Ticketmaster. For concerts with Ticketmaster Resale, the pri-
mary and resale ticket availabilities are shown on the same seat
map (for an example, see Figure 1). In 2014, Ticketmaster
received $900 million from ticket r esales (Ingham 2015).
Moreover, Ticketmaster has been trying to extend its de facto
monopoly in the primary market to the resale market by block-
ing other resale platforms. For example, after signing on as the
exclusive resale partner of the Golden State Warriors (GSW) in
2012, Ticketmas ter w arne d GSW season-ticket owners th at
their tickets would be revoked if resold outside Ticketmaster.
Consequently, StubHub saw an 80% decrease in resale trans-
actions of GSW season tickets (Dinzeo 20 15). Ticketmaster
also introduced the “Paperless Ticket” system (also known as
“Credit Card Entry”) for some events, which requires consu-
mers to show the credit card used to buy the ticket and a photo
ID to enter the concerts, making reselling through other resale
platforms very difficult for consumers.
2
Consumers can still
resell their paperless tickets through Ticketmaster because it
can change the ticketholder’s information in its own database.
Tianxin Zou is Assistant Professor of Marketing, Warrington College of
Business, University of Florida, USA (email: [email protected]).
Baojun Jiang is Associate Professor of Marketing, Olin Business School,
Washington University in St. Louis, USA (email: [email protected]).
1
See https://www.statista.com/outlook/264/109/event-tickets/united-
states#market-users.
2
See https://www.ticketmaster.com/mileycyrus/faq.html.
Journal of Marketing Research
2020, Vol. 57(4) 659-676
ª American Marketing Association 2020
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0022243720917352
journals.sagepub.com/home/mrj
The public reacted negatively to Ticketmaster’s anticompe-
titive practices. StubHub emailed its customers warning that
companies ‘like Ticketmaster’ are moving to restrictive
paperless systems, which could kill the secondary market for
tickets” (Indiviglio 2011). StubHub also sued Ticketmaster and
GSW in 2015 for creating illegal market conditions, although
the lawsuit was later dismissed (Rovell 2015). The Paperless
Ticket system has also led to drastic disputes. For example, a
spokesman for Consumer Action, a consumer advocacy group,
argued that “[it] is wrong to deprive consumers of the right to
fairly sell, trade or give away the ticket” (Pender 2017). An
article in The Atlantic also blamed Ticketmaster for
“extend[ing] its near monopoly of ticketing to the secondary
market” (Indiviglio 2011). As of 2019, five U.S. states, includ-
ing Colorado ( Colorado Consumer Protection Act 2017), Con-
necticut (An Act Concerning the Sale of Entertainment Event
Tickets on the Secondary Market 2017), New York (NY Arts &
Cult Aff L §25.30 2015), Virginia (Ticket Resale Rights Act
2017), and Utah (Ticket Transferability Act 2019), have passed
legislations requiring ticket issuers to offer tickets that can be
resold on any resale sites. Ten other states, including Arizona
(AZ HB2560 2019), Florida (FL SB392 2012), Indiana (IN
HB1331 2020), Massachusetts (MA H1893 2011), Minnesota
(MN SF425 2011), Missouri (MO HB255 2017), New Jersey
(NJ S1728 2018), North Carolina (NC H308 2011), Rhode
Island (RI H5362 2019), and Texas (TX HB3041 2013), have
previously discussed or are currently considering similar bills.
The Virginia legislation was sponsored by state delegate David
B. Albo, who lost $400 because he was unable to resell his two
paperless tickets for Iron Maiden to his friends. Albo said that
the legislation “would help consumers, given Ticketmaster’s
near-monopoly over big-venue ticket sales nationwide” (Voz-
zella 2017). It is widely believed that Ticketmaster’s control of
the resale business will create a ticket-intermediary monolith
that will increase the primary-ticket price and harm the welfare
of musicians and consumers.
This article, using the concert-ticket market as an example,
builds an analytical model to examine how the integration of
the primary and the resale platforms (vs. two independent plat-
forms) will affect the primary platform, the resale platform, the
consumers, and the upstream suppliers (e.g., musicians). Our
main analysis considers two scenarios. In the independent-
platforms case, the primary platform and the resale platform
are owned by independent parties. This scenario reflects the
situation in which Ticketmaster did not enter the resale market.
In the integrated-platform case, an integrated platform mono-
polizes both the primary and the resale markets. This setting
captures the situation in which Ticketmaster enters the resale
market and uses Paperless Ticket to prevent consumers from
reselling tickets on other resale platforms. We also examine a
model extension to study the scenario in which the integrated
platform competes with an independent resale platform in the
resale market (i.e., the integrated platform does not preclude
other resale platforms). Figure 2 illustrates these three cases.
In our model, some consumers a re uncertain in the first
period about whether they can a ttend the concert, and that
uncertainty is resolved in the second period. Consumers are
heterogeneous in their probabilities of being able to attend the
concert and their valuations of the concert. If a consumer buys
a ticket in the first p eriod, she can resel l it to other consumers
on the resale platform in the second period. Consumers can
buy tickets from either the primary or the resale plat form, but
if the demand exceeds the supply on a platform, consumers
may not be able to get a ticket from that platform with some
probability. The musician chooses the ticket’s face price and
the venue size (the number of tickets). In the independent-
platforms case, the primary and the resale platforms set their
service fees independently. I n the integrated-pla tform c ase,
Figure 1. Seat map of a concert enrolled in Ticketmaster resale.
660 Journal of Marketing Research 57(4)
the integrated platform decides the service fees for both mar-
kets. The fin al primary-tic ket price paid by c onsu me rs is the
sum of the face price and the service fee of the primary
platform. In essence, the musician and the primary platform
constitute a distribution channel in the primary market. The
equilibrium resale price is jointly determined by the demand
and the supply in the resale market. Consumers have rational
expectations about the future prices and the probabilities
of bein g able t o get a ticket from either t he primary or the
resale mar ket.
The conventional wisdom held by many legislators, news
media, and consumer advocacy groups in the previous exam-
ples would predict that because primary tickets and resale tick-
ets are perfect substitutes to consumers, an integrated platform,
which decides the service fees for both the primary and the
resale markets, will tend to charge higher fees in both markets
than those that two independent platforms will charge. Thus,
platform integration—a monopoly’s control of both the pri-
mary and the resale platforms—will make the consumers and
the musician worse off. However, we show that the opposite
can happen—platform integration can increase the welfare of
both the consumers and the musician. The intuition hinges on
the spillover effect from the primary market to the resale mar-
ket. A lower primary-ticket price will convince more consu-
mers with relatively low likelihood of attending the concert to
buy tickets in the first period. These consumers are more likely
to resell tickets later, which increases the supply in the resale
market and generates more resale transactions. In other words,
lowering the price in the primary market has a positive spil-
lover effect on th e resale market, potentially increasing the
resale profit. In the integrated-platform case, because the inte-
grated platform receives profits from both markets, it will have
an incentive to internalize the spillover effect by lowering the
primary-ticket service fee (and thus the final price) to increase
its resale profit. By contrast, in the independent-platforms case,
the primary platform does not have such an incentive because it
will not receive any resale fees. Thus, platform integration can
potentially benefit consumers because of the lowered price in
the primary market. Furthermore, the integrated platform’s
extra incentive to reduce the primary-ticket price will alleviate
double marginalization in the primary-market channel, which
will tend to increase the musician’s optimal venue size, leading
to more consumers being served. As a result, the musician, the
platform, and consumers can all be better off.
We also find that the musician and consumers can become
better off when t he integrate d platform has no competition
from any third-party resale platform than when it has resale
competition, even when the resale service fee is higher in the
absen ce of resale platform competition . This is because the
lower the integrated platform’s market share of the resale mar-
ket, the weaker the platform’s incentive to reduce its primary-
ticket service fee. Thus, the double-marginalization problem in
the primary-market channel can be exacerbated. Furthermore,
we show that an integrated platform can also have an incentive
to lower the resale fee to boost primary sales, because consu-
mers become more inclined to buy tickets from the primary
market anticipating a lower fee for their potential ticket resales,
consequently making consumers better off. In other words,
there is also a spillover effect from the resale market to the
primary market. Using data from Ticketmaster.com and Stub-
Hub.com, we provide some correlational empirical support for
our predictions.
In another extension, we discuss how the presence of scal-
pers, who buy t ickets with the sole intention of reselling them
at higher prices, affects the market outcome . We find that, in
the integrated-platform case, the existence of a small number
of scalpers can l ead to a lower ticket price, a higher profit for
the musician, and higher consumer surplus. This is because
scalpers are more likely to resell tickets than ordinary con-
sumers, so the integrated platform can earn more resale profit
if more scal pers buy from the primary market. Therefore, the
integrated platform has an i ncentive to keep the primary-
ticket price low enough to attract the scalpers, which can
further a lleviate the double-marginalization p roblem and ben-
efit the musician and consumers.
We want to emphasize that, although our main analysis
focuses on the concert-ticket market, the main insights of this
article can be generalized to broader market settings. Essen-
tially, if the supply in one market positively depends on the size
of another market, then letting an integrated entity control both
markets can lower the final price and allevia te the double-
marginalization problem (if any) in the latter market, which
can benefit all channel members in that market as well as con-
sumers. For example, when more consumers buy new books,
Musician
Primary
Platform
Resale
Platform
Consumers
Independent Platforms
Resale
Platform
Primary
Platform
Consumers
Integrated Platform
Resale
Platform
Primary
Platform
MusicianMusician
Consumers
Competing Resale Platforms
Independent
Resale Platform
Figure 2. Three types of market structures.
Zou and Jiang 661
more will resell their used books; when more consumers buy
new cars, more will share their cars on peer-to-peer car-sharing
platforms. Note that these market settings are very different
from the markets for complementary products, where it is the
product demand (rather than supply) in one market that posi-
tively depends on the size of another market (Cournot 1838). In
fact, in the aforementioned e xamples, from the consumer’s
perspective, the products (fi rsthand tickets and secondhand
tickets, new books and used books, driving a purchased car and
driving a rented car) are substitutes rather than complements.
The conventional belief—stronger competition between firms
selling substitutes will lead to lower prices, alleviate double
marginalization in distribution channels, and benefit consu-
mers—may no longer hold in markets with spillover effects.
We also illustrate these points with a general model.
Literature Review
This research contributes to the economics and marketing lit-
erature on secondary markets for event tickets. Most previous
studies have focused on whether allowing consumers or scal-
pers to resell tickets is beneficial to event organizers and con-
sumers. C ourty (2003b) shows that when consumers are
uncertain about their valuations at the time of purchase, allow-
ing resales cannot increase the event organizer’ s profit. Geng,
Wu, and Winston (2007) examine a similar setting and show
that allowing resales only before the announ cement of the
second-period price can strictly increase the event organizer’s
profit. Courty (2003a) shows that the existence of scalpers will
limit the event o rganizer’s ability of intertemporal price dis-
crimination and hurt its profit. Karp and Pe rloff (2005) find
that the event organizer can benefit from the entry of scalpers if
they can perf ect ly pr ice-di scrimina te consumers. Su (2010)
shows that the presence of scalpers will increase an event
organizer’s profit because the event organizer can sell tickets
to scalpers early and transfer the inventory risk to them. Cui,
Duenyas, and O
¨
zge (2014) find that an event organizer can
benefit from lower resale transaction costs and from selling
consumers an option for buying tickets later. Liao (2019) finds
that partiall y allowing ticket scalping can induce consumers to
buy tickets early, thus benefiting the event organizer. Several
studies have empirically examined how the existence of resale
markets can affect the primary market. Cusumano, Kahl, and
Suare z (2008) show that Craig slist’s entry into the concert-
ticket resale market raises the primary-ticket prices for popular
musicians but lowers those for the less popular ones. Leslie and
Sorensen (2014) find that the existence of resale markets can
increase the allocation efficiency by 5% for major rock con-
certs, but a third of the increase is offset by the ticket brokers’
costly efforts of getting tickets early and the resale transaction
costs. Lewis, Wang, and Wu (2019) show that the presence of a
secondary market for season tickets of a Major League Base-
ball team increases the demand for season tickets in the pri-
mary market. By contrast, secondary-market regulations, such
as minimum-list-price policies, will reduce the demand for
season tickets.
Our article differs from the aforementioned literature in two
fundamental aspects. First, that literature all considers a direct-
selling setting. This work is the first to study how the resale
market can influence the strategic interaction between different
channel members in the primary market (i.e. the [upstream]
musician and the [downstream] ticket platform). Second, the
extant literature focuses on whether the musician or the social
planner should allow consumers or scalpers to resell tickets. By
contrast, our research examines how the musician and consu-
mers are affected by whether the primary platform and the
resale platform are owned and operated by an integrated entity
or independent entities. We find that platform integration can
reduce equilibrium service fees on both platforms, alleviate
double marginalization in the primary-market channel, and
benefit all parties (i.e., the musician, the primary platform, and
consumers) at the same time.
Our article also relates to the literature on retail competition.
The general conclusion of this li terature is that integrations
between downstream retailers will reduce competition and
raise the final retail prices, intensifying double marginalization
and making both the upstream manufacturers and the consu-
mers worse off (Harutyunyan and Jiang 2019; Li 2002; Pad-
manabhan and Png 1998; Tirole 1988; Zhang 2002). This is the
rationale for the antitrust regulations against many horizontal
mergers (Hovenkamp and Shapiro 2017). In contrast, our arti-
cle shows that platform integration can lower the final ticket
price in the primary market and increase the welfare of the
musician and c onsumers. The difference in findings arises
because of the positive spillover effects between primary and
resale platforms, which are absent in markets with competing
retailers in general.
This article also contributes to the literature on secondary
markets for used goods. Swan (1970, 1972, 1975) shows that
the existence of the used-goods resale market will not limit a
monopoly seller’s profits. Rust (1986) shows that if consumers
endogenously decide when to resell their durable goods, the
monopolist firm may purposely reduce the durability of its
product. Anderson and Ginsburgh (1994) find that when con-
sumers hav e heterogene ou s p ref ere nces over n ew and u sed
goods, a used-goods market can benefit a monopoly seller by
allowing it to price-discriminate consumers. Purohit and Stae-
lin (1994) consider a car manufacturer selling to end consumers
and rental companies, both of which resell their used cars on
the resale market. They show that a higher substitutability
between used rental cars and new cars will harm the manufac-
turer but benefit the dealers. Desai and Purohit (1998) consider
a car manufacturer’s leasing and selling policies in a market
with consumers’ reselling of their used cars; they find that the
manufacturer may choose leasing, selling, or both, depending
on the depreciation rates of sold versus leased cars. Hendel and
Lizzeri (1999) find that a monopolist can benefit f rom the
secondary market even though the used-go ods market will
compete with the new-goods market. Shulman and Coughlan
(2007) study a monopoly manufacturer’s optimal pricing deci-
sion when the retailer can buy back and resell used products.
They find that under certain conditions, the manufacturer may
662 Journal of Marketing Research 57(4)
find it optimal not to sell any new goods in the second period.
The aforementioned literature mainly considers the situation in
whi ch consumers use a durable product for a period of time
before they resell it. By contrast, in our model, concert tickets
can be used only once but can be purchased at different times, and
consumers are ex ante uncertain whether they can attend the
concert. Our research question—how the integration of the pri-
mary and the resale platfor ms will affect the musician,
the platform, and the consumers—is also novel and practically
relevant.
Model
Consider a musician (denoted by M) who plans to organize a
future concert in a city. He sells the tickets via a primary ticket
platform (d enoted by P).
3
The musician decides the size of
performance venue to rent. His cost for renting a venue is
c N, where N is the venue size (the total number of available
seats) and c>0isaconstant.Let
N denote the size of the
largest venue in the city, so N
N. As is typically the case
for Ticketmaster, the musician will choose the face price f for
the tickets, and then the primary platform will set a service fee
for consumers.
4
Let p denote the final price that a consumer
pays for a ticket. Equivalently, the primary platform’s per-
ticket service fee is p f.
5
Without loss of generality, we assume that there is a unit
mass of consumers (indexed by i) in the market. Consumers are
heterogeneous in their valuations for the concert. A fraction a
of consumers are “avid fans,” denoted by A, whose valuation
for the concert is V
A
if they can attend it. The rest of the
consumers ( a fraction 1 a) are “casual fans,” denoted by
C, whose valuation for the concert, conditional on attending,
is V
C
< V
A
. Consumers ex ante are uncertain about whether
they will hav e future time conflicts with the concert, e.g. a
friend’s party. Because avid fans value the concert more than
casual fans, they are more likely to choose the concert over the
conflicting event than casual fans do. Let r
i
be the probability
that consumer i can attend the concert. For tractability, we
assume r
i
¼ 1 for avid fans and r
i
*uniform 0; 1ðÞacross the
population of casual fans. In the Web Appendix, we relax this
assumption by numerically analyzing a model in which both
avid and casual fans have the same probability of attending the
concert, to show that all the main results remain qualitatively
unchanged. Each consumer ex ante knows her own r
i
, but the
platforms cannot identify each consumer’s type. If a consumer
does not attend the concert, her utility from the concert is
normalized to zero. Therefore, a type- i consumer has probabil-
ity r
i
of having v
i
¼ V
i
and probability 1 r
i
of having
v
i
¼ 0. Each consumer buys at most one ticket. The tie-
breaking rule is that consumers will buy tickets if they are
indifferent between buying a ticket and not buying.
Consumers can buy their tickets in two periods. In the first
period, casual fans are uncertain about whether they can attend
the concert, but in the second period the uncertainty is resolved.
Consumers who bought tickets in the first period can choose to
resell their tickets on the resale platform (denoted by R) in the
second period, even if they can attend the concert themselves.
Let r denote the resale price. To acquire a ticket, consumers
can buy it from the primary platform at p or from the resale
platform at r. In practice, resale platforms (e.g., StubHub,
Ticketmaster) usually charge a percentage fee for resale trans-
actions. Let k 2 0; 1½denote the resale platform’s percentage
resale service fee, so a consumer will receive 1 kðÞrfor
reselling her ticket. The main analysis considers the case of
exogenous service fee k and discusses the main insights. We
also study an extension in which the platforms can endogen-
ously choose k.
Next, we describe how the equilibrium resale price r
is
determined in our model. A natural candidate for r
is the
market-clearing resale price at which the number of consumers
willing to resell their tickets (the resale supply) is equal to the
number of consumers willing to buy resale tickets (the resale
demand). However, such a market-clearing resale price may not
exist in our setting. This is because in the second period, con-
sumers’ ex-post valuations of attending the concert, v
i
,canonly
be V
A
,V
C
, or zero, so both the resale demand and the resale
supply are non-continuous functions. To identify a unique equi-
librium resale price r
,weassume r
to be the maximum resale
price that clears the supply in the resale market with all resale
tickets sold at r
. This definition is conceptually similar to the
marketing-clearing price.
6
Note that r
will be V
A
,V
C
,orzero
in equilibrium. Table 1 exhibits several examples of the equili-
brium resale price in different resale-supply scenarios in which
the resale demand comes from 10 fans with willingness-to-pay
of $10 and 20 fans with willingness-to-pay of $5.
One can show that, when
N a (i.e., the largest venue in the
city cannot hold all avid fans), the musician will set the ticket’s
face price f ¼ V
A
, and the primary platform and the resale
platform will receive zero surplus. We focus on the more inter-
esting case of
N> a for the remainder of the article. To obtain
3
For ease of exposition, we refer to a platform as “it,” the musician as “he,”
and the consumer as “she.”
4
In practice, typically, musicians set the ticket’s face prices and Ticketmaster
makes all tickets available for sale at the same time. Ticketmaster merely sells
the tickets on behalf of the musicians. (For details, see https://help.
ticketmaster.com/s/article/Purchase-Policy.) Note also that Ticketmaster sets
the service fees for tickets on a concert-by-concert basis. For evidence of
Ticketmaster setting different service fees for different concerts with the
same or similar ticket face prices, see the Web Appendix.
5
It is equivalent to assume that the primary platform charges a percentage fee
of p fðÞ= f. In practice, Ticketmaster charges percentage fees only in the
resale market but not in the primary market. For details, see Figure D1 in the
Web Appendix. Moreover, the main analysis assumes that the platform does
not dynamically adjust its price. In the Web Appendix, we prove that all results
remain qualitatively the same when the platform can dynamically adjust its
price.
6
The definition implies that for any resale price r> r
, the resale demand will
be smaller than the resale supply, and that for any r r
, the resale demand
will be greater than or equal to the resale supply.
Zou and Jiang 663
closed-form solutions, we assume that N 2 a= 1 þ aðÞ.
7
These conditions are equivalent to N= 2 N

a < N.
The timeline of the game is as follows. First, the musician
decides the venue size N 2 0;
N

and the ticket’s face price f.
The primary platform subsequently sets the final ticket price p
(in effect charging a service fee p f per ticket). In the first
selling period, consumers will decide whether to buy tickets
from the primary market. In the second period, consumers learn
whether they can attend the concert. Those who successfully
bought tickets in the first period can opt to resell their tickets in
the resale market. Those without a ticket can choose to buy a
ticket from either the primary platform (if tickets have not sold
out) or from the resale market, and if they want to buy a ticket,
they will try to buy from the cheaper platform first if ticket
prices are different on the two platforms. If the demand exceeds
the supply on a platform, tickets will sell out on that platform
and consumers who fail to get a ticket from that platform can
then decide whether to buy from the other platform. Whenever
demand exceeds supply, consumers are assumed to have equal
chances of getting a ticket. Figure 3 illustrates the event
sequence, and the derivation of consumers’ utility functions
are relegated to the Web Appendix.
Our main analysis considers two scenarios regarding
whether the primary and the resale platforms are operated by
the same entity. In the case of independent platforms (denoted
by IDP), the primary and the resale platforms are operated by
independent entities that maximize their respective profits.
This case reflects the situation in which Ticketmaster (the pri-
mary platform) has not entered the resale market. In the case of
integrated platform (denoted by INT), the two platforms are
owned by the same entity that maximizes the joint profit of the
two platforms. This case reflects the situation in which Ticket-
master enters the resale market and uses its Paperless Ticket
system to prevent consumers from reselling tickets on other
platforms. Comparing these two cases helps us examine how
Ticketmaster’s control of the resale market will affect the musi-
cian and consumers. In a later extension, we will examine a
scenario in which an int egrated platform competes with the
independent resale platform in the resale market. Table 2 pro-
vides a summary of the major notations.
Analysis
We solve for rational-expectation subgame-perfect equilibria.
In such equilibria, the musician, the primary platform, the
resale platform, and consumers have rational expectations
about the resale price and the consumers’ probability of getting
a ticket from a platform. Given the final price p, the resale
percentage fee k, and the venue size N, there may exist mul-
tiple equilibria with different consumer beliefs on how many
consumers will buy tickets in the first period. If the belief is that
many consumers will buy tickets in the first period, consumers
may also want to buy tickets early because they believe that
there will be few tickets left in the second period. However, if
the belief is that few consumers will buy tickets in the first
period, consumers may also postpone buying the ticket until
they know whether they can attend the concert. To pin down a
unique equilibrium, we introduce the concept of the “buying-
spree equilibrium.” We define the buying-spree equilibrium as
the rational-expectation subgame-perfect equilibrium that,
among all possible rational-expectation subgame-perfect equi-
libria, has the highest number of consumers trying to buy tick-
ets in the first period.
8
In the Web Appendix, we prove that the
buying-spree equilibrium is unique in our setting. For concise-
ness, we use “equilibrium” to refer to the unique buying-spree
equilibrium in the rest of the article.
Note that when k<1 ðV
C
= V
A
Þ, or equivalently when
1 kðÞV
A
> V
C
, a casual fan will resell her ticket if the resale
price is r ¼ V
A
regardless of whether her realization of v
i
is V
C
or zero. By contrast, when k 1 ðV
C
= V
A
Þ,orequivalently
1 kðÞV
A
V
C
, a casual fan will not resell her ticket if she has
v
i
¼ V
C
. We divide our analysis into two cases depending on
whether k 1 ðV
C
= V
A
Þ or k<1ðV
C
= V
A
Þ.
The Case of High Resale Percentage Fee
k 1 V
C
=V
A
½ðÞ
This subsection considers the case with k 1 ðV
C
= V
A
Þ.In
this case, the casual fans will not resell their tickets when their
realized valuation is v
i
¼ V
C
. We solve the game by back-
ward induction. First, we examine the consumers’ buying and
reselling decisions given N, f, and p. Clearly, choosing
N < a is a strictly s uboptimal strategy for t he musician,
because he can earn a strictly higher profit by setting N ¼ a and
Table 1. Examples of Equilibrium Resale Prices r
:
Supply of Resale Tickets Equilibrium r
5 fans want to resell tickets $10
25 fans want to resell tickets $5
35 fans want to resell tickets $0
Notes: Fans reselling tickets are assumed to have zero valuations here (i.e., not
being able to attend the concert).
7
This assumption is to ensure closed-form solutions for the full equilibrium
outcome. Our main results will qualitatively hold as long as
N is not too large.
We thank an anonymous reviewer for pointing out that our result applies to
situations in which the musician cannot serve all consumers in the market. In
practice, the venue size is usually limited (e.g., due to physical constraints) and
the potential demand often exceeds the capacity limit, especially for popular
artists. Ginsburgh and Throsby (2013) show that 43% of the concerts are sold
out in their sample, and the sell-out rates are higher than 85% for artists such as
Madonna, Billy Joel, Elton John, and Garth Brooks. Moreover, as we will
demonstrate in the “Discussion and a General Model” section, our main
insight does not actually require these modeling details of the concert-ticket
industry.
8
This is a reasonable assumption especially for more pop ular concerts. In
reality, consumers often rush to buy tickets as soon as tickets are released,
and many concerts sell out in the first few hours. For example, The Rolling
Stones sold out 75,000 tickets in 51 minutes for their “14 on Fire” tour in Paris
in 2014 (RFI 2014).
664 Journal of Marketing Research 57(4)
f ¼ V
A
. Moreover, in the Web Appendix, we also show that the
primary platform (in the independent-platforms case) and the
integrated platform (in the integrated-p latform case) will set
p 2 1 kðÞV
A
; V
C
y V
C
1 kðÞV
A
½½[V
C
; V
A
fg
,
where y 1
ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
1aðÞaa1þ2NðÞa
2
2N
2
½
p
1aðÞN
2 0; 1ðÞ. Thus, in the
rest of this subsection, we present the analysis only for the vari-
able region with a N
Nand p2 1 kðÞV
A
;½
V
C
y V
C
1 kðÞV
A
½[V
C
; V
A
fg
. Lemma 1 sum-
marizes how the final price p affects the equilibrium market
outcome.
Lemma 1: Suppose p 2 1 kðÞV
A
; V
C
y V
C
1ð½½
kÞV
A
 [ V
C
; V
A
fgand N 2 a; N

. In equilibrium,
(a) if p ¼ V
A
, all avid fans will buy tickets from the pri-
mary market in the first period, casual fans will not buy
any tickets, no resale transactions happen, and the pri-
mary platform’s profit is p
P
¼ V
A
fðÞa.
(b) if p ¼ V
C
, all avid fans will buy tickets from the pri-
mary market in the first period, all casual fans with
realized valuation v
i
¼ V
C
will try to buy tickets from
the primary market in the second period, no resale
Decisions of musicians
and plaorms
Decisions of musicians
and plaorms
B 1 Bu
Musician decides N
and f
Plaorm decides p
Buy now?
Can
aend?
Have ckets
No
Don’t have
ckets
Yes
Successfully
get ckets?
Yes
No
Can
aend?
Don’t have
ckets
Resell ckets
Resell?
Aend
Concert
Yes
No
Yes
No
No
Buy from
primary or resale
mkt?
Yes
Successful?
Yes
Not buy
Primary or Resale
No, choose
another choice
Figure 3. Sequence of events.
Table 2. Table of Notations.
N,
N
Actual venue size and maximum venue size
v
i
A consumer’s valuation of the concert
r
i
A consumer’s probability of being able to attend a concert
V
A
,V
C
Valuations of avid fans and of casual fans, respectively
c Marginal cost for the musician
f Ticket face price
p Ticket final price in the primary market
r Resale price
k Resale percentage fee
a Population of avid fans
b Population of scalpers
p
M
; p
I
, p
P
,
p
R
Profits of the musician, the integrated platform, the
primary platform, and the resale platform,
respectively
INT The subscript denoting the “integrated-platform case”
IDP The subscript denoting the “independent-platforms case
Zou and Jiang 665
transactions happen, and the primary platform’s profit is
p
P
¼ V
C
fðÞN.
(c) if 1 kðÞV
A
p V
C
y V
C
1 kðÞV
A
½,
casual fans with r
i
> r
¼
p 1kðÞV
A
V
C
1kðÞV
A
and all avid fans
will try to buy tickets in the first period and can success-
fully get a ticket with probability N= D
1
,where
D
1
¼ a þ 1 aðÞ1 r
ðÞN is the first-period
primary-market demand. In the second period, the equi-
librium resale pric e is r
¼ V
A
, the resa le supply is
S
R
¼ N= D
1
ðÞD
1
aðÞ1 r
ðÞ=2½,andtheresale
demand is D
R
¼ 1 N= D
1
ðÞ½a S
R
. Th e pr ofits
of the primary plat form a nd the resa le platform are
p
P
¼ p fðÞN and p
R
¼ kV
A
S
R
, respectively.
When p V
C
, no casual fans will buy from the primary mar-
ket in the first period, so there will be no consumers reselling
tickets in the second period. By contrast, when
1 kðÞV
A
p V
C
y V
C
1 kðÞV
A
½, tickets will
sell out, and some casual fans will try to buy tickets in the first
period and later resell their tickets if they cannot attend the
concert. An important observation is that, when p decreases
in this parameter region, more casual fans with lower r
i
will
try to buy and can successfully get tickets from the primary
market in the first period (technically, 1 r
increases when
p decreases), and these consumers are more likely to resell
their tickets. Therefore, a lower primary-ticket price ( p) will
increase the resale supply, S
R
(i.e., dS
R
= dp<0). We call this
effect the spillover effect from the primary market to the resale
market. Moreover, in our case, a decrease in p will also
increase the resale demand, D
R
(i.e., dD
R
= dp<0Þ. The intui-
tion is that when p decreases, more casual consumers will try to
buy tickets in the first period, reducing the avid fans’ probabil-
ity of successfully getting tickets from the primary market, so
more avid fans need to buy tickets from the resale market. As a
consequence, the lower the final ticket price in the primary
market ; the more resale transactions and the higher profit for
the resale platform.
Decisions of the platform and the musician. Next, we compare the
decisions of the platform and the musician in the independent-
platforms case and in the integrated-platform case. We start by
analyzing the platform’s decisions conditional on the musi-
cian’s choice of f and a N
N.
First, consider the case of independent platforms. The pri-
mary platform maximizes its own profit p
P
, which is
p
P
pðÞ¼
V
A
fðÞa; if p ¼ V
A
;
V
C
fðÞN; if p ¼ V
C
;
p fðÞN; if 1 kðÞV
A
p V
C
y V
C
1 kðÞV
A
½:
8
>
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
>
:
ð1Þ
The primary platform will never choose p< V
C
, because it can
already sell all tickets at p ¼ V
C
. In equilibrium, the primary
platform will set p to either V
C
or V
A
, both precluding any
resale transaction in the second period.
9
The primary platform
will set p ¼ V
A
when the population of avid fans is suffi-
ciently large ( a> NV
C
fðÞ= V
A
fðÞ); otherwise, the pri-
mary platform will set p ¼ V
C
.
Next, we consider the integrated-platform case. In this case,
the integrated platform maximizes the joint profit of the pri-
mary and the resale platforms, p
I
¼ p
P
þ p
R
, which is
p
I
pðÞ¼p
P
pðÞþp
R
pðÞ
¼
V
A
fðÞa; if p ¼ V
A
;
V
C
fðÞN; if p ¼ V
C
;
p fðÞN þ kV
A
S
R
; if 1 kðÞV
A
p V
C
y V
C
1 kðÞV
A
½:
8
>
>
>
>
>
<
>
>
>
>
>
:
ð2Þ
In contrast to the independen t-platforms case, even when
p < V
C
, further reducing p can increas e t he integrated
platform’s profit if the spillover effect is sufficiently strong.
Specifically, if reducing p can significantly expand the
resale supply such that dS
R
= dp < N= kV
A
, then reducing
p will increase the integrated p latform’s profit when
p 2 1 kðÞV
A
; V
C
y V
C
1 kðÞV
A
½
fg
. Proposition
1 establishes one of the key results of our research: compared
with the independent-platforms case, an integrated p latform
has extra incentives to lower its price in the primary market
to facilitate resale transactions.
Proposition 1: (Platform i ntegration can reduce the
primary-ticket price.) In the integrated-pla tform case, if
a min
2kðÞV
A
2V
C
kV
A
;
V
A
2kðÞ2f
V
A
2þNkðÞ2f
N
no
, the integrated plat-
form will set p ¼ 1 kðÞV
A
< V
C
, which is lower than its
level in the independent-platforms case. The equilibrium
resale price is r
¼ V
A
. The profits from the primary mar-
ket and the resale market are p
P
¼ 1 kðÞV
A
Nand p
R
¼
kV
A
N1aðÞ
2
, respectively. The integrated platform’s total
profit is p
I
¼ NV
A
1
k1þaðÞ
2

f
hi
.
In contrast to the case of independent platforms where
p V
C
, the integrated platform will choose some p < V
C
if the population of avid fans ( a) is low enough. In this case,
although the integrated platform generates less profit from the
primary market than when setting p ¼ V
C
, the platform will
gain more profit from the resale market. The intuition that a
must be low is as follows. When the population of avid fans is
low, many primary tickets will be bought by the casual fans and
thus there will be many resale transactions. In other words, the
spillover effect is stronger when a is lower. Note that, in our
setting, the integrated platform is willing to reduce p only if the
resulting equilibrium resale price is high ( r
¼ V
A
). This is
9
This “no resale” result relies on our assumption that avid fans with tickets
will always attend the concert. One should interpret the “no resale” result as
that in the independent-platforms case the primary platform will have less
incentive to encourage first-period purchases from casual fans.
666 Journal of Marketing Research 57(4)
because a high r
implies a high resale profit margin, which
incentivizes the platform to boost resale transactions.
One might expect that the integrated platform will have stron-
ger incentives to set p< V
C
to encourage casual fans to buy
tickets in the first period when the resale percentage fee ( k) is
higher, because each resale transaction can generate a higher
transaction fee for the platform. However, Proposition 1 indi-
cates the opposite: The condition a min
n
2kðÞV
A
2V
C
kV
A
;
V
A
2kðÞ2f
V
A
2þNkðÞ2f
N
o
is more likely to be true when k is lower. When
k is lower, casual fans will be more willing to buy tickets in the
first period, because they will pay a lower resale service fee if
they cannot attend the concert. As a result, the integrated plat-
form can induce casual fans to buy tickets in the first period
by only slightly reducing p, which will not significantly
reduce its primary-market profit. Therefore, the integrated
platform is more likel y to set p< V
C
to facili tate resale trans-
actions. In addition, the condition a min
n
2kðÞV
A
2V
C
kV
A
;
V
A
2kðÞ2f
V
A
2þNkðÞ2f
N
o
is more likely to be t rue when the venue size
( N) is larger, because there will be more casual fans being
able to get tickets in the first period and reselling in the second
period. In other words, the spillover effect is stronger when N
is larger, or mathematically, dS
R
= dp is proportional to N.
Next, we investigate the musician’s optimal decisions for
the face price f and the venue size N. We start with the
independent-platforms case. Lemma 2 characterizes the musi-
cian’s equilibrium choices of the venue size ( N
IDP
) and the
face price ( f
IDP
) in the independent-platforms case.
Lemma 2: Let a
IDP
N1
ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
V
A
V
C
V
A
c
q

.Inthe
independent-platforms (IDP) case:
(a) If a a
IDP
, the musician will choose N
IDP
¼ N and
f
IDP
¼
NV
C
aV
A
Na
, the primary platform will set
p
IDP
¼ V
C
, all avid fans will buy tickets in the first period,
and casual fans with realized v
i
¼ V
C
will try to buy
tickets from the primary platform in the second period.
The corresponding consumer surplus is a V
A
V
C
ðÞ.
(b) If a > a
IDP
, the musician will choose N
IDP
¼ a and
f
IDP
¼ V
A
, the primary platform will set p
IDP
¼
f
IDP
¼ V
A
, avid consumers will buy tickets from the
primary platform, and casual fans will not buy tickets in
either period. The corresponding consumer surplus is
zero.
When the population of a vid fans is sufficient ly large
(a > a
IDP
), the primary platform will have a strong incentive
to set p ¼ V
A
and serve only the avid fans, unless the ticket’s
face price f is so low as to a lso make serving casual fans
profitable. Because setting such a low f will severely reduce
the musician’s profit margin, he will rather choose a small
venue size (N ¼ a) and a high face price (f ¼ V
A
) to serve
only the avid fans and extract all their surplus himself. By
contrast, if a a
IDP
, the musician will choose a large venue
size (N ¼
N) and a low face price (f ¼
NV
C
aV
A
Na
), and the
prima ry platform will set p ¼ V
C
in equilibrium, in which
case both the avid fans and the casual fans are served. As we
have shown, no resale transaction will occur in either case.
We now investigate the integrated-platform case. Lemma 3
characterizes themusician’s equilibrium choices of the venue size
(N
INT
)andthefaceprice(f
INT
) in the integrated-platform case.
Lemma 3: Let a
INT
min
2kðÞV
A
2V
C
kV
A
;
n
N1
ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
V
A
kV
A
k N
2
þ81þN
ðÞ
V
A
cðÞ

q
V
A
k N
4V
A
cðÞ
2
4
3
5
g
.Inthe
integrated-platform (INT) case:
(a) If a a
INT
, the musician will choose N
INT
¼ N and
f
INT
¼ 1
Nk 1þaðÞ
2
Na
ðÞ

V
A
, the integrated platform will
set p
INT
¼ 1 kðÞV
A
, and all consumers will try to
buy tickets in the first period. The equilibrium resale
price is r
¼ V
A
, and the equilibrium volume of resale
transactions is
N1aðÞ
2
. Consumer surplus is
N aV
A
k þ
1aðÞV
C
1kðÞV
A
½
2
hi
.
(b) If
2kðÞV
A
2V
C
kV
A
< a a
IDP
, the musician will choose
N
INT
¼ N and f
INT
¼
NV
C
aV
A
Na
, the integrated plat-
form will set p
INT
¼ V
C
, all avid fans will buy tickets
in the first period, and casual fans with realized v
i
¼ V
C
will try to buy tickets in the primary market in the second
period. Consumer surplus is a V
A
V
C
ðÞ.
(c) If a is not in the regions in (a) or (b), the musician will
choose N
IDP
¼ a and f
IDP
¼ V
A
, the integrated plat-
form will set p
IDP
¼ f
IDP
¼ V
A
. Avid consumers will
buy tickets in the primary market, and casual fans will not
buy tickets in either periods. Consumer surplus is zero.
10
Part (a) of Lemma 3 i s the interesting case: When
a a
INT
, in equilibrium the integrated platform will charge
p< V
C
to boost resale transactions. Proposition 1 shows that
when a is low and N is large, an integrated platform will have
a strong incentive to reduce p to serve more casual fans even if
the musician charges a relatively high face price, f . Thus, the
musician will be more inclined to choose a larger N to serve
both the avid and the casual fans.
Comparison of the independent-platforms case and the integrated-
platform case. Having characterized the equilibrium outcomes
in the independent-platforms ca se and in the integr ated-
platform case in Lemmas 2 and 3, Proposition 2 proceeds
to compare the equilibrium outcomes of those two cases to
determine how platform integration will affect the market
outcome.
10
The parameter regions of a in (a) or (b) may be empty.
Zou and Jiang 667
Proposition 2: (Platf orm integration can alleviate double
marginalization.) Suppose a
IDP
<a a
INT
. Compared with the
independent-platforms case (IDP), in the integrated-platform
case (INT):
(a) The musician will choose a strictly lower ticket face
price and a strictly larger venue size, resulting in a
strictly lower final price (i.e., f
INT
< f
IDP
,N
INT
>
N
IDP
, and p
INT
< p
IDP
).
(b) The musician’s profit is strictly higher and the plat-
form’s profits in both markets are strictly higher (i.e.,
p
M; INT
> p
M; IDP
, p
P; INT
> p
P; IDP
and p
R; INT
> p
R; IDP
).
Consumer surplus is also strictly higher.
Proposition 2 shows that when a is in an intermediate range,
platform integration can actually lead to a lower final ticket
price, higher profits for the musician and the platforms, more
consumers attending the concert, and higher consumer surplus
at the same time. Platform integration will give the platform a
stronger incentive to lower the final price p (conditional on the
musician’s choice of f) to serve both the avid and the casual
fans, which will alleviate double marginalization i n the
primary-market distribution channel. This implies that plat-
form integration can allow more of the reduction in face price
to be passed through to consumers, so the musician is more
likely to choose a larger venue size N and charge a lower face
price f to s erve more c onsumers. Specific ally, when
a
IDP
< a a
INT
, the musician will choose a smaller venue
(N
IDP
¼ a) if the platforms are independent but will choose
a larger venue ( N
INT
¼ N) if the platforms are integrated. In
such a case, platform integration can lead to an all-win outcome
for the musician, the platforms, and the consumers.
In summary, platform integration can benefit consumers, the
musician, and the primary and the resale platforms in two ways.
First, Proposition 1 implies that platform integration will incenti-
vize the platform to lower the final price in the primary market to
internalize the spillover effect, which can benefit consumers.
Second, Proposition 2 suggests that platform integration can alle-
viate double margi nalization in the prima ry-market channel,
which can benefit consumers, the musician, and the platforms.
We want to point out how our setting relates to the setting of
markets for complementary products (e.g., game consoles and
video games). In a complementary product setting, lowering
the price in one market will also lead to more transactions in
another market, so a monopoly controlling both markets can
result in lower prices and higher consumer surplus compared
with having two independent firms control the two markets
(Cournot 1838). This finding is similar to ours. However, the
underlying mechanism is very different. In the setting of com-
plementary products, a lower price in one market will increase
the demand in another market (for the complementary prod-
uct). By contrast, in the setting of concert tickets, a lower ticket
price in the primary market will increase the su pply in the
resale market. We show that, even though primary tickets and
the resale tickets are (perfect) substitutes, letting an integrated
entity controlling both markets can still benefit consumers
because of the aforementioned spillover effect.
As a side note, besides alleviating double marginalization,
platform integration can enhance the musician’s incentive to
induce resales to extract more surplus from the resale transactions.
As we explain next, the integrated platform can more efficiently
extract consumer surplus by facilitating resales, thus the musician
may also charge an appropriate face price to extract some of the
profit gain for himself. This effect will harm consumers but can
benefit musicians. To see this effect, let us consider the case with
N ¼
N. If p ¼ V
A
, the platform can extract all avid fans sur-
plusbut cannot serve any casual fan. If p ¼ V
C
, then all avid fans
can successfully get tickets from the primary market in the first
period. There will be no resale in this case, and all avid fans have a
surplus of V
A
V
C
although the surplus of some casual fans
can be extracted. By contrast, if p ¼ 1 kðÞV
A
< V
C
, all con-
sumers will try to buy tickets in the first period, so some avid fans
cannot get tickets from the primary market and have to pay a
higher price V
A
to buy from the resale market. Thus, more con-
sumer surplus can be extracted if p is lowered to 1 kðÞV
A
to
facilitate resales, because at the lowered p, all surplus of avid fans
who purchase from the resale market is extracted (relative to when
p ¼ V
C
) whilesome casual fans are also served (relative to when
p ¼ V
A
). In the integrated-platform case, the musician can cap-
ture part of the integrated platform’s profit gain from the resale
transactions by raising his face price. By contrast, in the
independent-platforms case, the musician cannot do so because
the primary platform does not receive any profit gain from resale
transactions. To summarize, platform integration can incentivize
the musician to induce resales to indirectly extract some profit
gain from the resale market.
Platform integration’s effect on the musician’s incentive to
induce resales is manifested in our results. As shown in Lemma
2 and 3, if a< min a
IND
; a
IDP
fg
, in both the independent-
platforms and the integrated-platform cases, the musician will
choose N ¼
N, so platform integration does not affect the equi-
librium market coverage through alleviation of double margin-
alization. However, in this parameter region, platform integration
will have an effect on the musician’s incentives to induce resales
to extract more consumer surplus. Compared with the
independent-platforms case, consumer surplus is lower, the equi-
librium face price and the musician’s profit are higher in the
integrated-platform case. We also find that, in this parameter
region, platform integration will reduce the social welfare. This
is because, though all
N tickets are consumed, in the independent-
platforms case, all avid fans will obtain tickets in equilibrium
whereas, in the integrated-platform case, some avid fans will not
be able to get tickets from either the primary or the resale market.
The Case of Low Resale Percentage Fee
ðk<1 ½V
C
=V
A
Þ
If k<1 ðV
C
= V
A
Þ, all casual fans will be willing to resell
their tickets when r ¼ V
A
even when their realized valuation
668 Journal of Marketing Research 57(4)
is v
i
¼ V
C
. However, if r V
C
, casual fans will not resell
their tickets if v
i
¼ V
C
.
Lemma 4: If k<1 ðV
C
= V
A
Þ and N> a, then r
V
C
as long as some consumers will resell their tickets in
equilibrium.
Note that, in our setting, the equilibrium resale price r
can
only be V
A
,V
C
, or zero. Lemma 4 shows that the resale price
cannot be high ( V
A
) if k is relatively low. This is because if
r
¼ V
A
, the low k will encourage all casual consumers to
buy tickets in the first period and resell them later regardless of
their realized v
i
, which will increase the resale supply so much
that r
can no longer be su stained at V
A
—a contradiction.
Because the resale platform’s profit per resale transaction is
k r
,if k<1 ðV
C
= V
A
Þ and r
V
C
, the integrated
platform will have limited incentive to reduce p to boost resale
transactions. It turns out that in equilibrium the integrated plat-
form will never cho ose p< V
C
, so there will be no resale
transactions. Thus, if k<1 ðV
C
= V
A
Þ, platform integration
will not affect the equilibrium outcome.
Extensions and Empirical Support
In this section, we consider several model extensions. First,
we examine how t he presence of scalpers will aff ect the mar-
ket outco me. Second, we s tudy the optimal resale percentage-
fee decisions in both the independent-platforms case and the
integrated-platform case. Third, we consider the scenario that
the i ntegrated platform competes with an independent resale
platform in the resale market. Finally, we provide some cor-
relational, suggestive empirical support for our theoretical
results.
The Impact of Scalpers
Oftentimes, many scalpers buy tickets from the primary market
and resell them at higher prices. According to Scott Cutler, chief
executive officer of StubHub, nearly half of ticket resales on
StubHub come from “professional traders (Sullivan 2017). It
is generally believed that scalpers make profits by raising the
effective prices paid by consumers and thus harm the welfare of
consumers and the musicians. The official Twitter account of the
rock band LCD Soundsystem derogated scalpers as “parasites”
(Horowitz 2017). Scalpers usually use computer bots to buy
hundreds of tickets within minutes after tickets start selling.
To combat scalpers, former U.S. President Bara ck Obama
signed the Better Online Ticket Sales Act in 2016, which
restricts the use of software bots to obtain and resell event tick-
ets. Many U.S. states have also passed legislations banning or
restricting scalping behaviors. Ticketmaster has also introduced
the Verified Fan system, which can block 90% of buying
attempts from ticket scalpers (Brooks 2017). In this extension,
we investigate how the existence of scalpers affects ticket prices,
profits of the musician and platforms, and the consumers under
different market structures (i.e., whether the primary and the
resale platforms are independent or integrated).
In this extension, we assume that besides the unit mass of
regular consumers (avid and casual fans), there are b number
of scalpers who can also buy tickets from the primary platform
and resell them on the resale platform. Scalpers have zero
valuation for attending the concert, but they move earlier than
regular consumers in the first period when buying tickets from
the primary platform. The main model in the previous section is
the special case of b ¼ 0. For closed-form analytical solutions,
we focus on the parameter region of b 2 a 1 þ aðÞ
N

=
1 aðÞ(i.e., there are only a small number of scalpers). To
illustrate the most interesting result, in this extension, we ana-
lyze the case with k 1 V
C
= V
A
ðÞand a N
2 a= 1 þ aðÞ. We show that, even when scalpers have the abil-
ity to buy tickets earlier than regular consumers, the scalpers’
presence can still result in lower ticket prices and higher con-
sumer surplus and make both the musician and the integrated
platform better off.
11
This contrasts the independent-platforms
case, in which one can show that, in the same assumed para-
meter region, the presence of scalpers has no effect on the
market outcome, because the primary platform will find it
optimal to set a sufficiently high final ticket price ( p) so that
no scalpers will buy tickets in equilibrium.
First, we analyze the integrated-platform case. We begin by
examining the subgame in which the integrated platform will
choose its optimal final price p, conditional on the musician’s
choices of N and f. Similar to the previous section, it is not
optimal for the musician to choose a venue size N< a,sowe
need only consider the c ase of
N N a. Note that the
scalpers will buy tickets from the primary market only if p is
low enough (i.e., p 1 kðÞ
c
r
) so that they will make a
positive profit from reselling.
12
Lemma 5 shows that it may
be optimal for the integrated platform to choose p low enough
such that scalpers will buy tickets in the primary market.
Lemma 5: Given the musician’s choices of N and f , the
integrated platform will choose p ¼ 1 kðÞV
A
if and only if
a<
2N V
A
V
C
ðÞ
NbðÞkV
A
1and f< V
A
1
k1þaðÞNbðÞ
2NaðÞ
hi
,inwhich
case all scalpers and regular consumers will try to buy tickets
in the first period, the equilibrium resale price is r
¼ V
A
, and
the integrated platform’s total profit is p
I
¼
1þa
2
bkV
A
þ
NV
A
1
k1þaðÞ
2

f
hi
.
It is worth mentioning that when the conditions in Lemma 5
are satisfied, the integrated platform’s profit, p
I
, increases with
the number of scalpers ( b). Letting scalpers buy tickets in the
first period tends to increase transactions in the resale market
because scalpers are more likely (with probability one) to resell
the tickets than regular consumers. Consequently, the presence
of the scalpers can strengthen the spillover effect. Relatedly,
11
Our results are qualitatively the same if scalpers and regular consumers have
equal probability of getting tickets.
12
We use ^ over variables to indicate a consumer’s rational prediction of
those variables.
Zou and Jiang 669
letting scalpers buy tickets in the first period can reduce the
avid fans’ probability of getting tickets from the primary mar-
ket, so more avid fans will need to buy from the resale market
at the high resale price r
¼ V
A
, and thus the integrated plat-
form can better extract avid fans’ surplus. Therefore, the inte-
grated platform has an incentive to let scalpers buy tickets from
the primary market to create transactions in the resale market.
To attract scalpers, the integrated platform n eeds to keep
p 1 kðÞ
c
r
so scalpers can make a profit. In other words,
the integrated platform will have an extra incentive to lower the
final price on the primary platform.
Define
a
SCP
min N1
ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
1b=
N
p
ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
V
A
kV
A
k
N
NbðÞþ81þ
NðÞV
A
cðÞ½
p
V
A
k
NbðÞ
4V
A
cðÞ
hi
;
n
2
NV
A
V
C
ðÞ
NbðÞV
A
k
1
g
. We characterize the impact of scalpers on the
market outcome in Proposition 3.
Proposition 3: (Platform integration can make the presence
of scalpers be neficial to regular consumers.) Suppose
V
A
> 2= 2 kðÞ½V
C
, a
INT
< a a
SCP
and b< 2 a½
1 þ aðÞ
N= 1 aðÞ. In the integrated-platform case, the pres-
ence of scalp ers will in equi librium strictly reduce the final
ticket price p
. Moreover, if a> a
IDP
is also satisfied, then
the presence of scalpers will strictly increase the musician’s
profit, the integrated platform’s profit and the consumer surplus
(excluding scalpers).
Contrary to the conventional belief that scalpers will raise
the effective ticket prices paid by consumers and thus reduce
consumer surplus, Proposition 3 shows that, with an integrated
platform, the presence of a small number of scalpers can ben-
efit the platform, t he musician, and the consumers. This is
because the presence of scalpers can induce the integrated plat-
form to strategically reduce the primary-market price to
encourage resale transactions ; which can alleviate double mar-
ginalization in the primary market.
Note that Proposition 3 does n ot suggest that scalpers
will always benefit consumers and the musician. Indeed,
there are several boundary conditions for the presence of
scalpers to be beneficial. For example, if the population of
avid fans is small such that a a
INT
, the platform will find
it optimal to s et p ¼ 1 kðÞV
A
to serve both casua l fans
andavidfansevenwhentherearenoscalpers.Underthis
condition, scalpers will strictly reduce the consume r surplus.
Moreover, the segment size of scalpers bðÞcannot be too
high. If there are too many scalpers, consumers a re worse
off because fewer tickets will be available for regular con-
sumers in the primary market, forcing too many avid fans to
buy res ale tickets at higher pr ices. It is also important to
point out that scalpers can benefit the consumers only when
the primary and the resale platforms are integrated. In the
independent- pla tforms case, the prima ry platform does not
receive any resale profit, so it has n o incentive to reduce the
final ticket price to attract scalpers. Thus, with an indepen-
dent resale plat form, the pre sence of scalpers will not facil-
itate channel coordinationintheprimarymarket.
Endogenous Resale Percentage Fee k
Our main model has assumed the resale percentage fee k to be
exogenous. In this model extension, we a naly ze the optimal
choice of k for the resale platform. In the independent-
platforms case, afte r the musici an has chosen the venue siz e
N and the face pric e f, the prima ry pl atform will set the fina l
price p and the resale platform will set the resale percentage
fee k simultaneously. In the integrated-platform case, the
integrated platform jointly chooses p and k to maximize its
profit. Under the original assumpt ion that avid fans are always
able to attend the concert, in the independent-platforms case,
the primary plat form wi ll al ways find it optimal to choose
p V
C
such that no casual fans will buy in t he f irst period.
Thus, the resale pla tform wil l rece ive z ero profit regardless of
its choice of k. Therefore, to allow for a more meaningful
comparison of how platform integration affects the equili-
brium resale percentage fee k
,weneedbothavidfansand
casual fans to have so me probab ility of not being a ble to
attend the concert. To this end, we introduce another random
interruption that can prevent a consumer from attending the
concert (in addition to the random factor in the main model).
Suppose that the new interruptive events (e.g., mandatory out-
of-town travels or personal emergencies) have a probability d
of occurrence, in which case a consumer (both avid and
casual) will be unable to attend the conce rt. Thus, one can
show that overall, avid fans can attend the concert with prob-
ability r
A
¼ 1 d, a nd the casual fans can atten d with prob-
ability r
C
* uniform 0; 1 dðÞ. Under this assumpt ion, even
if only avid fans buy tickets in the first period, there will still
be resale transactions because avid fans resell the ir tickets in
the second period with probability d. To concisely present the
results, we consider the case of d ! 0
þ
. The qualitative
results will still hold true as long as d is not too large. Pro-
position 4 reveals how platform integration will change the
resale percentage fee.
Proposition 4: (Platform integration can reduce
the resale percentage fee.) When a <
N1½
ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
V
A
V
C
ðÞV
A
V
C
ðÞ
N
2
þ81þ
NðÞV
A
cðÞ
½
p
V
A
V
C
ðÞ
N
4V
A
cðÞ
,aninte-
grated platform will choose a strictly lower resale percent-
age fee ( k) than that chosen by an independent resale
platform (i.e., k
INT
< k
IDP
).
Proposition 4 reveals that when t he population of avid fans
is low, the integrated platform’s optimal resale percentage fee
k
INT
will be lower than an independent resale platform’s
choice, k
IDP
. The intuition is as follows. A lower resale per-
centage fee can incentivize consumers to buy tickets in the
primary market, because their future potential reselling cost is
lower. In other words, lo we ring k will hav e a positive spil-
lover effect from the resale market to the prima ry ma rket. An
integrated platform can internalize the spillover effect and
tends to reduce k.
670 Journal of Marketing Research 57(4)
Competition in the Resale Market
This model extension examines the scenario in which the inte-
grated platform competes with an independent resale platform
in the resale market. This represents the situation in which
Ticketmaster competes with StubHub in the resale market. The
competition in the resale market will tend to reduce the resale
percentage fee k. For tractability, we assume that the integrated
platform and the independent resale platform have the same
resale percentage fees k
COMP
with k
COMP
< k. A fraction f of
resale-ticket buyers buy from the integrated platform, and a
fraction 1 f of resale-ticket buyers buy from the independent
resale platform. Although we do not model how k
COMP
and f
are determined in equilibrium, our assumptions reflect that the
resale service fee will decrease under competition in the resale
market, so we can analyze how competition in the resale market
will affect the equilibrium prices, profits and consumer surplus.
One can show that when k
COMP
<1 V
C
= V
A
ðÞ, the inte-
grated platform wil l choose a final ti cket price such that only
avid fans wi ll buy in the primary ma rke t in the first period, so
there will be no r esale transactions in the second period. In
other words, if the integrated platform anticipates that the
presence of a competing resale platform w ould reduce the
resale service fee from k to some k
COMP
<1 V
C
= V
A
ðÞ,
then the integrated platform will not reduce its price i n the
primary market to attract c asual fans to buy tickets in the first
period. Below, we analyze the more interesting case of
k
COMP
1 V
C
= V
A
ðÞ.
Compared with the integrated-platform case without resale
competition, one may intuit that introducing resale competition
will make consumers better off. Proposition 5 shows that, coun-
terintuitively, resale competition can make the musician and
the consumers strictly worse off, even though the resale service
fee, k, will decrease.
Proposition 5: (Resale competition can hurt consumers and
musicians.) Supp ose a
INT
>0and k
COMP
1 V
C
= V
A
ðÞ.
Then there exists f
>0 such that if f<f
, then resale com-
petition will strictly increase the final price p and strictly
reduce the musician’s profit and the consumer surplus.
When the integrated platform’s resale market share is low,
the integrated platform can capture only a small fraction (f)of
resale transactions. Thus, it will have little incentive to reduce
p to induce more transactions in the resale market. As a result,
the double-marginalization problem in the primary market is
less likely to be mitigated, so resale competition can reduce the
musician’s profit and the consumer surplus.
Suggestive Empirical Evidence
This subsection provides some suggestive empirical support for
our theoretical findings. We acknowledge that our empirical
results suggest only correlational associations rather than cau-
sal relationships. Moreover, the empirical setting is different
from our theoretical model setup for paperless tickets, though
in both settings the spillover effects between the primary and
the resale markets will influence the platforms’ pricing deci-
sions in a similar fashion. Thus, one should interpret the results
in this subsection as suggestive, indirect, correlational supports
for some of our theoretical predictions.
When musicians contract with Ticketmaster to sell tickets
on their behalf, they can choose whether to enroll in Ticket-
master Resale program. If they enroll, consumers will be able
to resell their tickets on both Ticketmaster and third-party
resale platf orms (e.g., StubHub). If they do not enroll, then
consumers will not be able to resell their tickets on Ticket-
master but can still resell on third-party resale platforms. Many
musicians do not enroll in Ticketmaster Resale because they
worry that doing so can encourage scalping and result in higher
prices (Knopper 2014). It is plausible that some musicians’
decisions on whether to enroll in Ticketmaster Resale are not
due to their profit-oriented concerns.
Our previous theoretical analysis suggests that platform
integration will weakly lower the equilibrium primary-market
price and th e resale fee percentage. Ticketmaster can profit
from both the primary and the resale markets for conc erts
enrolled in Ticketmaster Resale; thus, according to the insights
from our main models, Ticketmaster will have more incentives
to reduce its service fee in the primary market for those con-
certs than for concerts not enrolled in Ticketmaster Resale.
Moreover, for concerts enrolled in Ticketmaster Resale, Tick-
etmaster should have more incentives to reduce the resale ser-
vice fee than a third-party resale platform like StubHub that
does not have sales in the primary market.
Prediction 1: Ticketmaster will set lower service fees on the
primary platform for concerts with Ticketmaster Resale than
for concerts without Ticketmaster Resale.
Prediction 2: For concerts with Ticketmaster Resale, Ticket-
master will set lower resale percentage service fees than Stub-
Hub’s for the same concerts.
We manually collected data for all pop and rock concerts in
Missouri in 2018 that were on sale at Ticketmaster.com on
December 20, 2017. We excluded musicians promoted by Live
Nation, the parent company of Ticketmaster. We also excluded
concerts with general admission because of their unlimited
supply of tickets. A total of 62 concerts satisfy these conditions,
34 of which were enrolled in Ticketmaster Resale. A concert
usually has multiple price levels. Our data set contains 199
price levels in total for all the concerts, and we treat each price
level of a concert as an observation in our analysis. For each
observation, we collected the data on the ticket’s face price and
the primary-market per-ticket service fee on Ticketmaster,
13
whether the concert is enrolled in Ticketmaster Resale, and the
13
Some concerts also charge per-order “order processing fees” to “offset the
costs of ticket handling, shipping and support” (https://help.ticketmaster.com/
s/article/How-are-ticket-prices-and-fees-determined). Because we do not have
the data for order processing fees, and they are relatively small (usually below
$5 per order) compared with the per-ticket service fee, our analysis will use the
per-ticket service fee as a proxy for the total fees on Ticketmaster. We also
exclude some fees (e.g., facility charges) that are charged by other entities (e.g.,
the venue), because those fees are not Ticketmaster’s strategic decisions.
Zou and Jiang 671
concert’s promoter and venue information. In addition, we
manually collected data for a musician’s numbers of followers
on Last.fm (an online radio website) and on Songkick (an
online music community) as of December 21, 2018, to control
for the musician’s popularity. Table 3 shows the summary
statistics of some variables.
We examine how the enrollment of Ticketmaster Resale
affects the primary-market service fee on Ticketmaster with
the following regression:
ServiceFee
i
¼ b
0
þ b
1
TicketmasterResale
i
þ h FacePrice
i
ðÞþX
i
b þ E
i
: ð3Þ
TicketmasterResale
i
is a dummy variable for concert i‘s enroll-
ment in Ticketmaster Resale. h ðÞis a polynomial of the ticket’s
face price, which is specified as either a linear function or the
polynomial leading to the lowest Bayesian information criterion
(BIC) for the regression. X
i
is the vector of the control variables
such as the musician’s number of followers on Last.fm and that
on Songkick, and the event-promoter and the venue dummies.
Prediction 1 predicts that b
1
should be negative.
Table 4 summarizes the estimation results. A concert’s
enrollment in Ticketmaster Resale is negatively correlated
with its primary-market service fee on Ticketmast er. Enroll-
ment in Ticketmaster Resale is associated with a $1.15 drop in
service fe e on the primary platform, whic h translates to 11.1%
of the median primary-market service fe e on Ticketma ster.
The finding is consistent with Prediction 1 that the service
fee in the primary marke t is lower for con certs en rolle d in
Ticketmaster Re sale.
We also collected the resale percentage fees on Ticketmas-
ter and on StubHub for all 16 concerts enrolled in Ticketmaster
Resale between April 27, 2018 and December 31, 2018.
14
Fig-
ure 4 compares their resale percentage fees on Ticketmaster
with those on StubHub. For all these concerts, Ticketmaster
charges lower percentage fees than StubHub does. A paired
t-test also shows that Ticketmaster’s resale percentage fee is
lower than St ubHubs on average: mean TicketmasterðÞ¼
18 %, mean StubHubðÞ¼21:9%, t ¼ 16:19, p < :001. This
is consistent with Prediction 2—for concerts enrolled in Ticket-
master Resale, Ticketmaster will have more incentives to
charge a lower resale percentage fee than StubHub will.
Table 4. Estimation Results (Independent Variable: Primary-Market Service Fee).
Variables
(1)
OLS
(2)
OLS
(3)
OLS
(4)
Robust SD
Intercept 7.21***
(.43)
8.48***
(.79)
——
Ticketmaster Resale Enrolled? .88*
(.50)
1.77***
(.55)
1.15**
(.48)
1.15**
(.46)
Face price .06***
(.0039)
.06***
(.0029)
——
Higher-order polynomial of face price No No Yes Yes
Last.fm follower 1.6 10
7
(3.4 10
7
)
1.6 10
7
(2.8 10
7
)
1.6 10
7
(3.2 10
7
)
Songkick follower 7.0 10
7
(8.8 10
7
)
7.2 10
7
(7.5 10
7
)
7.2 10
7
(8.3 10
7
)
Promoter and venue fixed effect No Yes Yes Yes
Number of observation 199 199 199 199
R
2
.606 .946 .963 .963
*p < .1.
**p < .05.
***p < .01.
Notes: Standard deviations in parentheses. OLS ¼ ordinary least squares.
Table 3. Summary Statistics.
Variable Mean SD Median Min Max
Ticket face price ($) 81.75 63.51 59.00 15.00 345.00
Primary-market service fee ($) 12.26 5.37 10.35 4.85 29.80
Last.fm followers 898,731 949,743 635,605 0 4,328,799
Songkick followers 513,086 663,277 222,592 0 1,791,395
Ticketmaster Resale enrolled
a
.508 .501 1 0 1
a
Dummy variable equal to 1 if true, 0 otherwise.
14
We collected these data on April 26, 2018, so we were unable to find the
resale service fees on StubHub for concerts before this date.
672 Journal of Marketing Research 57(4)
Discussion and a General Model
One main message of this research is that, because of the pos-
itive spillover effect from the primary to the resale market (i.e.,
lowering the price and boosting sales in the primary market will
increase the resale supply), platform integration will incenti-
vize the platform to lower the final price in the primary market
to internalize the spillover effect, which will alleviate double
marginalization in the primary market (relative to the case of
independent platforms). In the concert-ticket context, the inte-
gration of the primary plat form and the resale platform can
make the musician, the platform, and the end consumers all
better off.
Even though our discussion has revolved around the
concert-ticket industry, whic h motivated our research, our
main qualitative insight—letting an integrated platform con-
trol both the primary and the secondary markets can lead to
lower prices and a win-win outcome for the firms and the
consumers—can be applicable to other markets with similar
spillover features. For example, when a retail platform (e.g.,
Amazon) sells both new a nd used b ooks, it may have an
incentive to lower the retail price for new books so that
more consumers will buy new books, so more consumers
will later sell their used books on the platform. Thus, the
double-marginalization problem in the primary channel for
new books (between the p ublisher and the retail platform)
can be a lleviated. Our qualitative findings can a lso be
applied to peer-to-peer product-sha ring mar kets, the p roduct
quality and channel-pricing aspects of which have been
studied in Tian and Jiang (2018) and Jiang and Tian
(2018). Some car manufacturers provide their own peer-t o-
peer car-sharing services. For example, Mercedes-Benz car
owners in Germany can rent out their cars to others on
Croove, Mercedes-Benz’s own peer-to-peer shar ing plat-
form. The insight of our researc h will predict that a car
manufacturer with its own peer-to-peer sharing platform can
have an extra incentive to lower its car prices, inducing
more consumers to buy ca rs and later rent out their (under-
utilized) cars on the manufacturer’s sharing platform, which
will increase the manufacturer’s p rofit from its sharing plat-
form. We acknowledge that such markets have some differ-
ences from the concert-ticket market (e.g., competit ion in
book and automobile markets are more intense, books and
cars are not single-use products and depre ciate o ver time,
car owners themsel ves m ay use the cars some of the time).
Nevertheless, our qualitative insight—that an integrated
platform, compared with independent platforms, tends to
charge lower prices and can benefit consumers—can be
generalized to related markets with positive cross-market
spillovers, where more transactions in one market will
increase the supply of another market.
We formalize this argument with a general model t hat
abstracts away from many institutional details of the concert-
ticket market. Consider two related markets—the primary mar-
ket and the secondary market. Let us label the primary market
as market A (e.g., the primary market of concert tickets or cars)
and the secondary market as market B (e.g., the ticket resale
market or the car-sharing market). Consumers’ valuation of a
product in market B can be the same as that in market A (as in
the case of concert ticket) or can be different from that in
market B (as in the case of used-goods or product-sharing
markets). The product prices in the two markets are p
A
and
p
B
, respectively. Consumers are indexed by i 2 I, where I
0
5
10
15
20
25
12345678910111213141516
eeFelaseRegatnecreP
Concert ID
Ticketmaster
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
9
1
0
1
1
1
2
1
3
1
4
1
5
1
6
C
o
nc
e
r
t
ID
T
i
c
k
e
t
m
a
s
t
er
StubHub
Figure 4. Resale percentage fee: Ticketmaster versus StubHub.
Zou and Jiang 673
represents the set of all consumers. Consumer i‘s probability of
buying the product from market A, conditional on p
A
and p
B
,
is P
i
¼ P
i
p
A
; p
B
ðÞ: We assume that q P
i
=q p
A
<0 (i.e., con-
sumers are less likely to buy from market A as p
A
increases). If
consumer i has bought a product in market A, she will have a
probability f
i
¼ f
i
p
B
ðÞof reselling or renting out the product
in market B. We assume that df
i
= dp
B
>0: for example, in the
concert-ticket market, consumers are more likely to resell their
tickets if the resale price is higher. The population of consu-
mers is normalized to one.
The demand in market A is D
A
p
A
; p
B
ðÞ¼
ð
i2I
P
i
di;
the supply in market B is S
B
p
A
; p
B
ðÞ¼
ð
i2I
P
i
f
i
ðÞdi.
Note that q D
A
=q p
A
¼
ð
i2I
q P
i
=q p
A
ðÞdi<0and
q S
B
=q p
A
¼
ð
i2I
q P
i
=q p
A
ðÞf
i
½di<0. These two
inequalities indicate that, in this general model , there is a
positive spillover effect from market A to market B—hold-
ing p
B
constant, a lower p
A
will increase not only the
demand in market A but also the supply in market B.
Next, we examine how the firms’ pricing decisions are dif-
ferent when the two markets are respectively controlled by two
independent platforms (the independent-platform case) versus
when they are controlled by an integrated platform (the
integrated-platform case). The demand in market B is denoted
by D
B
p
A
; p
B
ðÞwith q D
B
=q p
B
<0. Because the products in
the two markets are substitutes, we assume q D
B
=q p
A
>0. The
equilibrium price in market B is the market-clearing price p
B
,
at which D
B
p
A
; p
B

¼ S
B
p
A
; p
B

.Itcanbeshown
q p
B
q p
A
¼
q S
B
D
B
ðÞ=q p
A
q S
B
D
B
ðÞ=q p
B
0, because an increase in p
A
will
reduce S
B
(due to the spillover effect) and increase D
B
(due
to the substitution effect). Therefore, the prices in the two
markets tend to move in the same direction. The platform’s
per-transaction revenue in market B is k p
B
ðÞ, a function of
p
B
. For example, if the platform charges a percentage fee z in
market B, then k p
B
ðÞ¼z p
B
; if the platform charges a
fixed fee, then k p
B
ðÞis a constant. The platform’s marginal
cost in market A and B are c
A
and c
B
, respectively.
In the independent-platform case, platform A’s profit is
p
A
¼ D
A
p
A
; p
B

p
A
c
A
ðÞ. Assuming that p
A
is glob-
ally strictly concave with respect to p
A
, then platform A’s
optimal price, p
A; IDP
, is the unique solution to the first-order
condition given by Equation 4:
0 ¼
dp
A
dp
A
¼
ð
i2I
dP
i
dp
A
p
A
c
A
ðÞþP
i

di: ð4Þ
By contrast, the integrated platform’s profit will be p
INT
¼
p
A
þ p
B
¼ p
A
þ kp
B

c
B

S
B
p
A
; p
B

.If p
INT
is
globally strictly concave, the integrated platform’s optimal price
in market A, p
A; INT
will be the unique solution to:
0 ¼
dp
INT
dp
A
¼
dp
A
dp
A
þ
dp
B
dp
A
¼
dp
A
dp
A
þ kp
B

c
B

q S
B
q p
A
þ
qp
B
q p
B
q p
B
q p
A
: ð5Þ
The second and the third terms of Equation 5 show that the
integrated platform’s price p
A
in market A affects p
B
,its
profit in market B, in two ways. The second term,
kp
B

c
B

q S
B
q p
A
, represent s how the spillover ef fect
(whose size is q S
B
=q p
A
) affects the platform’s profit in mar-
ket B. This term is always negative, so the spillover effect due
to the decrease in p
A
will increase the integrated platform’s
profit. The third term, qp
B
=q p
B

q p
B
=q p
A

, represents
how the reduction of p
A
affects the platform’s profit in market
B through reducing p
B
. If the spillover effect is strong enough
such that
q S
B
q p
A
>
1
kp
B
ðÞ
c
B
qp
B
q p
B
q p
B
q p
A
,reducing p
A
will
increase the platform’s profit from market B ( dp
B
= dp
A
<0),
so dp
INT
= dp
A
< d p
A
= dp
A
. This implies p
A; INT
< p
A; IDP
(i.e.,
platform integration or monopoly control of the primary and
secondary markets will lead to a lower price in market A).
Moreover, the market-clearing price in market B will also
decrease because q p
B
=q p
A
0.
Conclusion
The main me ssage of this ar ticle is that musicians a nd con-
sumers can benefit from the primary ticket platform’s control
of the resale market. This is due to the positive spillover
effects between the prima ry market and the re sale market—
lowering the price or the service fee o n one platform will lead
to more transactions on the other platform. The integrated
platform will tend to internalize the posit ive spillover effect
by lowering the service fees in both markets, which can alle-
viate the double-marginalization problem in the primary mar-
ket, so the musician is more willing to choose a larger venue
size to serve more consumers. Consequently, the musician,
the platforms, and consumers c an be better off at the same
time. We also find that the presence of a small number of
scalpers can lead to lower ticket prices, higher prof its for the
musicians, and higher consumer surplus. Using data from
Ticketmaster and StubHub, we provide s ome empirical sup-
port for some of our theoretical predictions.
Our research has important implications for the ongoing
legislation movement on restricting a primary ticket platform’s
ability to block competitors in the resale market in many U.S.
states. The economic concern of such legislations is that plat-
form integration will increase the service fees in the primary
and resale markets, which will harm consumers and musicians.
In this article, we argue that such reasoning may be flawed
because it neglects an integrated platform’s incentive to stra-
tegically reduce the service fees to internalize the positive spil-
lover effect between the primary and the resale market. Our
policy suggestion is that the legislation should be more careful
674 Journal of Marketing Research 57(4)
in restricting the primary platform’s control of ticket resales or
the price coordination between primary and resale platforms.
This research is also related to antiscalping laws. It has
long been deba ted whe th er allowin g scal pin g coul d benefi t
the ticket sellers and consumers. This article provides another
reason why scalpers can potentially play a positive role in the
market—that i s, their presence may incentivize the integrated
platform (with both primary and resale marke t operations) to
set a lowe r final price in the primary market, which r educes
double marginalization in the primary market, potentially
making the musicians, the platform, and the consumers a ll
better off.
This article develops an analytical framework to analyze the
interaction among the musician, the primary platform, and the
resale platform in the concert-ticket industry. The framework
provides a foundation for future research on related topics such
as second-degree price discrimination. Our article also pro-
vides some correlational empirical support for our theoretical
predictions. We hope our research motivates future empirical
research to more systematically validate our insights or predic-
tions and to further explore how the welfare of the musicians
and consumers will be affected.
Acknowledgments
The authors thank Cexu n Jeffery Cai, Guangying Chen, Mushegh
Harutyunyan, Chuan He, Jay Ritter, Lin Tian, Yue Wu, Bo Zhou, and
seminar participants at the 2019 POMS Annual Conference, Cornell
University, University of Florida, Fudan University, Hong Kong Uni-
versity, University of Missouri, Nanyang Technological University,
Peking University, Saint Louis University, Shanghai University of
Finance and Economics, Rice University, and Washington University
in St. Louis for their helpful comments and suggestions. The authors
also thank the review team for their constructive suggestions.
Associate Editor
Kinshuk Jerath
Declaration of Conflicting Interests
The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to
the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.
Funding
The author(s) received no financial support for the research, author-
ship, and/or publication of this article.
ORCID iDs
Tianxin Zou https://orcid.org/0000-0002-6292-4298
Baojun Jiang
https://orcid.org/0000-0002-6159-2869
References
An Act Concerning the Sale of Entertainment Event Tickets on the
Secondary Market (2017), Connecticut Code, Public Act §17.28.
Anderson, Simon P. and Victor A. Ginsburgh (1994), “Price Discrim-
ination via Second-Hand Markets,” European Economic Review,
38 (1), 23–44.
Brooks, Dave (2017), “Ticketmaster’s Verified Fan Has Had 90%
Success Rate at Blocking Bots, Says Live Nation CEO Michael
Rapino,” Billboard (September 8), https://www.billboard.com/arti
cles/business/7957835/ticketmaster-verified-fan-90-percent-suc
cess-rate-rapino.
Colorado Consumer Protection Act (2017), Consumer and Commer-
cial Affairs § 6-1-718.
Cournot, Antoine Augustin (1838), Recherches sur les pr incipes
math
´
ematiques de la th
´
eorie des richesses. Paris: L. Hachette.
Courty, Pascal (2003a), “Some Economics of Ticket Resale,” Journal
of Economic Perspectives, 17 (2), 85–97.
Courty, Pascal (2003b), “Ticket Pricing Under Demand Uncertainty,”
Journal of Law and Economics, 46 (2), 627–52.
Cui, Yao, Izak Duenyas, and S¸. O
¨
zge (2014), “Should Event Organi-
zers Prevent Resale of Tickets?” Management Scien ce,60(9),
2160–79.
Cusumano, Michael A, Steven J. Kahl, and Feranondo F. Suarez
(2008), “Services, Industry Evolution, and the Competitive Strate-
gies of Product Firms,” Academy of Management Journal, 51 (2),
315–34.
Desai, Preyas and Devavrat Purohit (1998), “Leasing and Selling:
Optimal Marketing Strategies for a Durable Goods Firm,” Man-
agement Science, 44 (11, Part 2), S19–S34.
Dinzeo, Maria (2015), StubHub Sues NBA’s Warriors &
Ticketmaster,” Courthouse News (March 30), https://www.
courthousenews.com/stubhub-sues-nbas-warriors-ticketmaster/.
Geng, Xianjun, Ruhai Wu, and A ndrew B. Whinston (2007),
“Profiting from Partial Allowance of Ticket Resale,” Journal of
Marketing, 71 (2), 184–95.
Ginsburgh, Victor A. and David Throsby (2013), Handbook of the
Economics of Art and Culture, Vol 2. London: Newnes.
Harutyunyan, Mushegh and Baojun Jiang (2019), “The Bright Side of
Having an Enemy,” Journal of Marketing Research,56(4),
679–90.
Hendel, Igal and Alessandro Lizzeri (1999), “Interfering with Second-
ary Markets,” RAND Journal of Economics, 30 (1), 1–21.
Horowitz, Steven J. (2017), “The Concert Ticket Industry Is Still
Broken,” Vulture (May 2), http://www.vulture.com/2017/05/every
one-wants-concert-tickets-but-no-one-is-getting-them.html.
Hovenkamp, Herbert J. and Carl Shapiro (2017), “Horizontal Mergers,
Market Structure, and Burdens of Proof,” Yale Law Journal , 127
(7), 1996–2025.
Indiviglio, Daniel (2011), “Is Ticketmaster Trying to Eliminate Sec-
ondary Ticket Sales?” The Atlantic (February 27), https://www.
theatlantic.com/business/archive/2011/02/is-ticketmaster-trying-
to-eliminate-secondary-ticket-sales/71735/.
Ingham, Tim (2015), “Secondary Ticketing Sales Soar at Ticketmaster
in 2014,” Music Business Worldwide (March 3), https://www.
musicbusinessworldwide.com/secondary-ticketing-sales-soar-at-
ticketmaster-in-2014/.
Jiang, Baojun and Lin Tian (2018), “Collaborative Consumption:
Strategic and Economic Implications of Product Sharing,” Man-
agement Science, 64 (3), 1171–88.
Karp, Larry and Jeffrey M. Perloff (2005), “When Promoters Like
Scalpers,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy,14
(2), 477–508.
Zou and Jiang 675
Knopper, Steve (2014), “Is Ticketmaster’s New Resale Program Help-
ing or Hurting Fans?” Rolling Stone (May 27), https://www.roll
ingstone.com/music/news/is-ticketmasters-new- resale-program-
helping-or-hurting-fans-20140527.
Leslie, Phillip and Alan Sorensen (2014), “Resale and Rent-Seeking:
An Application to Ticket Markets,” Review of Economic Studies,
81 (1), 266–300.
Lewis, Michael, Yanwen Wang, and Chunhua Wu (2019), “Season
Ticket Buyer Value and the Secondary Market Options,” Market-
ing Science, 38 (6), 913–1084.
Li, Lode (2002), “Information Sharing in a Supply Chain with Hor-
izontal Competition,” Management Science, 48 (9), 1196–1212.
Liao, Chenxi (2019), “Scalpers: When ‘How Many’ Is the Question,”
working paper.
Padmanabhan, V. and I.P.L. Png (1998), “Manufacturer’s Returns Pol-
icies and Retail Competition, Marketing Science, 16 (1), 81–94.
Pender, Kathleen (2017), “Think Carefully Before Buying ‘Paperless’
Tickets That Require Credit Card Entry,” San Francisco Chronicle
(May 31), https://www.sfchronicle.com/business/networth/article/
Think-carefully-before-buying-paperless-11186609.php.
Purohit, Devavrat and Richard Staelin (1994), “Rentals, Sales, and
Buybacks: Managing Secondary Distribution Channels,” Journal
of Marketing Research, 31 (3), 325–38.
RFI (2014), “Rolling Stones Paris Gig Sold Out in 51 Minutes,”
(March 28), http://en.rfi.fr/asia-pacific/20140328-rolling-stones-
paris-gig-sold-out-51-minutes.
Roberts, Daniel (2013), “Taking Down Ticketmaster,” Fortune
(November 26), http://fortune.com/2013/11/26/taking-down-
ticketmaster/.
Rovell, Darren (2015), “StubHub’s Antitrust Lawsuit Against War-
riors, Ticketmaster Dismissed,” ESPN (November 5), http://www.
espn.com/nba/story/_/id/14063815/stubhub-antitrust-lawsuit-
golden-state-warriors-ticketmaster-dismissed.
Rust, John (1986), “When Is It Optimal to Kill Off the Market for
Used Durable Goods?” Econometrica, 54 (1), 65–86.
Shulman, Jeffrey D. and Anne T. Coughlan (2007), “Used Goods,
Not U sed Bads: Profitable Secondary Market Sales for a Durable
Goods Channel,” Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 5 (2),
191–210.
Smith, Ethan (2008), “Ticketmaster Buys Major Reseller,” The Wall
Street Journal (January 15), https://www.wsj.com/articles/
SB120036522352890281.
Su, Xuanming (2010), “Optimal Pricing with Speculators and Strate-
gic Consumers,” Management Science, 56 (1), 25–40.
Sullivan, Conor (2017), “‘Professional’ Sellers Behind 50% of Tickets
on Resale Sites,” Financial Times (March 15), https://www.ft.com/
content/91c680ca-04dd-11e7-ace0-1ce02ef0def9.
Swan, Peter L. (1970), “Durability of Consumption Goods,” American
Economic Review, 60 (5), 884–94.
Swan, Peter L. (1972), “Optimum Durability, Second-Hand Markets,
and Planned Obsolescence,” Journal of Political Economics,80
(3), 575–85.
Swan, Peter L. (1975), “Product Durability Under Monopoly and
Competition: Comment,” Econometrica, 45 (1), 229–35.
Thomas, Parker (2016) , “How StubHub Will Be Recog nized as a
Single Source for Ticketing,” Yahoo Finance (March 16), https://
financ e.yahoo.com/news/stu bhub-recogniz ed-single-source-ticket
ing-011011659.html.
Tian, Lin and Baojun Jiang (2018), “Effects of Consumer-to-
Consumer Product Sharing on Distribution Channel,” Production
and Operations Management, 27 (2), 350–67.
Ticket Resale Rights Act (2017), Code of Virginia, §59.1-466.6.
Ticket Transferability Act (2019), Utah Code, §13-56-201.
Tirole, Jean (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization.Cam-
bridge, MA: MIT Press.
Vozzella, Laura (2017), “Metalhead Va. Legislator Wants to Cut
Ticketmaster’s Control of Its Tickets on Resale Market,” The
Washington Post (January 28), https://www.washingtonpost.com/
local/virginia-politics/metalhead-va-leg islator-wants-to-cut-ticket
masters-control-of-resale-market/2017/01/28/a2df78d8-e4b4-
11e6-a547-5fb9411d332c_story.html.
Zhang, Hongtao (2002), “Vertical Information Exchange in a Supply
Chain with Duopoly Retailers,” Production and Operations Man-
agement, 11 (4), 531–46.
676 Journal of Marketing Research 57(4)
CopyrightofJournalofMarketingResearch(JMR)isthepropertyofAmericanMarketing
Associationanditscontentmaynotbecopiedoremailedtomultiplesitesorpostedtoa
listservwithoutthecopyrightholder'sexpresswrittenpermission.However,usersmayprint,
download,oremailarticlesforindividualuse.