MONETARY POLICY IN A NEW ERA
Ben S. Bernanke
Brookings Institution
October 2, 2017
Prepared for conference on Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy, Peterson Institute, Washington
DC, October 12-13, 2017. The author is a Distinguished Fellow at the Brookings Institution and
the Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy. I thank Olivier Blanchard, Donald Kohn,
and David Wessel for comments and Michael Ng for excellent research assistance.
1
In 2017, the flagship research conferences of the European Central Bank and the Federal
Reserveheld in Sintra, Portugal, and Jackson Hole, Wyoming, respectivelyhad something in
common: Both had official themes unrelated to monetary policy, or even central banking. The
ECB conference (theme: Investment and Growth in Advanced Economies) did include an
opening speech by President Mario Draghi on monetary policy and the outlook, before turning to
issues like the prospective effects of technological advances on employment. However, the
Fed’s meeting (theme: Fostering a Dynamic Global Economy), which included papers on topics
ranging from fiscal policy to trade to income distribution, made almost no mention of monetary
policy. Whether intended or not, the signal, I think, was clear. After ten years of concerted
effort first to restore financial stability, then to achieve economic recovery through dramatic
monetary interventions, central bankers in Europe and the United States believe that they see the
light at the end of the tunnel. They are looking forward to an era of relative financial and
economic stability in which the pressing economic issues will relate to growth, globalization, and
distributionissues that are the responsibility of other policymakers and not primarily the
province of central bankers.
Would that it were so simple. Although central bankers can certainly hope that the next
ten years will be less dramatic and demanding than the past ten, there will certainly be important
new challenges to be met. In this note, I focus selectively on two such challenges: the
implications of the secular decline in nominal interest rates for the tools and framework of
monetary policy; and the status of central banks within the government, in particular, the
questions of whether central banks should and will retain their current independence in making
monetary policy. As I will explain, the two challenges are related, in that the low-inflation, low-
interest-rate environment in which we now live calls into question some of the traditional
rationales for central bank independence.
The long-term decline in nominal interest rates is well known and has been extensively
studied (Rachel et al., 2015). The decline appears to be the product of many causes, including
lower inflation rates; aging populations in advanced economies (Gagnon et al., 2016a); slower
productivity growth and “secular stagnation” (Summers, 2015); global patterns of saving and
investment (Bernanke, 2005); and increased demand for “safe” assets (Del Negro et al., 2017;
Caballero et al., 2017). Some of these factors may reverse in the medium termfor example,
2
recent historically low rates of productivity growth could revert to more-normal levels (Byrne
and Sichel, 2017), and there is some evidence that the global savings glut may be moderating
(Chinn, 2017)which could lead to somewhat higher rates in the future. For now, though, the
combination of low nominal rates and the difficulty of reducing short-term interest rates (much)
below zero implies that monetary policymakers may have limited scope to address deep
economic slowdowns through the traditional means of cutting short-term interest rates. Recent
research by Kiley and Roberts (2017) illustrates the potential severity of the problem. Based on
simulations of econometric models, including the Fed’s main model for forecasting and policy
analysis, these authors show that the use of conventional, pre-crisis policy approaches could lead
to policy rates being constrained by the zero lower bound (ZLB) as much as one-third of the
time, with adverse effects on the Fed’s ability to hit its 2 percent inflation target or to keep output
near potential.
1
How should central banks respond? Outside of making a stronger case for proactive
fiscal policies, there are two broad possibilities (interrelated and not mutually exclusive). First,
rather than relying on the management of short-term interest rates alone, as assumed by Kiley
and Roberts, monetary policymakers could make greater use of new tools developed in recent
years. In the first main section of this paper, I review some of these tools. I argue that both
forward guidance and quantitative easing are potentially effective supplements to conventional
rate cuts, and that concerns about adverse side effects (particularly in the case of quantitative
easing) are overstated. These two tools can thus serve to ease the ZLB constraint in the future, as
argued by Yellen (2016). Two other toolsnegative interest rates and yield curve controlare
less likely to play important roles, at least in the United States. European and Japanese
policymakers have successfully employed negative rates, but overall they appear to have
relatively modest benefits (because the option to hold cash limits how far negative rates can go),
as well as some offsetting costs (related to their effects on certain financial institutions and
markets). Yield curve control, or the direct management of longer-term interest rates, has been
adopted by the Bank of Japan and makes sense in the current Japanese context. However, as I
1
As some major central banks have employed modestly negative rates, conventional usage now often refers to the
“effective lower bound” (ELB) on interest rates rather than the ZLB. The Federal Reserve has not used negative
rates, however. Since I am focusing on the Fed here, for simplicity I’ll stick with the ZLB acronym.
3
will discuss, the depth and liquidity of the markets for U.S. government securities would make it
difficult for the Fed to peg rates beyond a horizon of two years or so.
Although unconventional tools can increase the potency of monetary policy, the ZLB is
still likely to be a binding constraint on the monetary response to a downturn that is more
serious, or which occurs when rates remain (like today) below neutral levels. A second broad
response to the problem is to modify the overall policy framework, with the goal of enhancing
monetary policymakers’ ability to deal with such situations (Williams, 2017). Focusing on the
case of the Federal Reserve, in the second principal section of the paper I briefly consider two
proposed alternatives: (1) raising the Fed’s inflation target from its current level of 2 percent,
and (2) introducing a price-level target. I argue that a higher inflation target has a number of
important drawbacks: It would, obviously, lead to higher average inflation (possibly inconsistent
with the Fed’s mandate for price stability); and, more subtly, it implies a Fed reaction function
that theoretical analyses suggest is quite far from the optimal response. A price-level target
performs better on both counts, as 1) it is fully consistent with the goal of price stability, perhaps
even more so than an inflation target; and 2) it implies a “lower-for-longer” response to periods
when rates are at their ZLB, which approximates what theory tells us is the optimal approach.
However, a price-level target can be problematic in the face of supply shocks, and the switch to a
price-level target from the current inflation targeting approach would be a significant
communications challenge. In the latter part of the section, I propose and discuss a third possible
alternative: a “temporary price-level target” that kicks in only during periods in which rates are
constrained by the ZLB. I argue that the adoption of a temporary price-level target would be
likely to improve economic performance, relative to the current framework. Importantly, it
would do that while both maintaining price stability and requiring only a relatively modest shift
in the Fed’s framework and communication policies. However, this proposal is a tentative one at
this stage, and more analysis would be needed before taking it further.
Beyond the problems arising from low nominal interest rates, monetary policymakers
also face challenges to central bank independence (CBI). The challenge to CBI has been
heightened by the political blowback that followed the financial crisis. But, as already noted,
questions about CBI are also related to the change in the macroeconomic and interest-rate
environment, linking this issue to the themes of the first part of the paper. In the United States,
the doctrine of CBI emerged, in part, from the inflationary experience of the 1960s and 1970s,
4
which was blamed in part on undue political influence on monetary policymakers. Following
these events, both formal models and informal conventional wisdom held that, to avoid pressures
to overheat the economy and allow higher inflation, the Fed needed greater independence from
politics. However, the inflation-centric rationale for CBI looks a bit outdated in a world in which
inflation and nominal interest rates are too low, rather than too high; and in which politicians
have criticized central banks for being too expansionary rather than not expansionary enough.
Indeed, the same logic that holds that CBI is necessary to avoid excess inflation can be turned on
its head, to imply that CBI is a barrier to the fiscal-monetary coordination needed to combat
deflation (Eggertsson, 2013).
The last principal section of the paper briefly takes up these issues. I argue that the case
for CBI has always been broader than the anti-inflationist argument, and that CBI should remain
in place in the new economic environment. At the same time, I contend that the case for CBI is
instrumental, that it depends on costs and benefits rather than on philosophical principles, so that
the limits of independence appropriately depend on the sphere of activity under consideration
and on economic conditions. The general principle of CBI thus does not preclude coordination
of central bank policies with other parts of the government in certain situations.
DEFEATING THE ZLB: UNCONVENTIONAL POLICY TOOLS
Central bankers in 2008 faced extraordinarily difficult challenges, in particular the
combination of a deep recessionwhich made a sharp easing of monetary conditions
necessaryand the proximity of short-term interest rates to zero, which made easing difficult.
In response, monetary policymakers employed a number of unconventional policy measures.
Which ones will become part of the standard toolbox? In what order or combination might the
various tools of monetary policy be used in the future? In this section, I comment on these
issues. I take as given that management of a short-term policy rate (e.g., the federal funds rate in
the United States) will remain the primary tool, so long as the ZLB is not binding. I won’t have
much to say about the technicalities of monetary policy implementation (e.g., the distinction
between a “floor” and “corridor” system for managing short-term rates), although
unconventional policies (such as quantitative easing) can at times complicate implementation. I
discuss, sequentially, forward guidance, quantitative easing, negative rates, and yield curve
control (the management of longer-term yields).
5
Forward guidance
The non-standard tool on which central bankers are most likely to rely in the next easing
cycle is forward guidance, or communication about the expected or intended future path of the
policy rate. The Fed used variants of forward guidance in the Greenspan era, for example, in
references to keeping rates low for “a considerable period” (Federal Open Market Committee,
2003). Even earlier, a number of central banks experimented with forward-looking policy
commitments, a notable case being the Bank of Japan’s zero-interest-rate policy (ZIRP), in
which the BOJ said that it would not lift rates from zero until certain conditions had been met
(Bank of Japan, 1999). The prices of longer-term financial assets (including those most closely
tied to economic activity, such as corporate bonds, mortgages, and stocks) depend on not only
the current setting of the policy rate but on its entire expected future path. Consequently, central
bank “open-mouth operations” that influence market expectations of future policies can affect
financial conditions today, even if the short-term policy rate is close to its effective lower bound
(Guthrie and Wright, 2000).
Forward guidance comes in a number of forms. A useful distinction is between Delphic
and Odyssean forward guidance (Campbell et al., 2012). Delphic guidance is a simple statement
of how monetary policymakers see the economy and interest rates as likely to evolve. Delphic
guidance is advisory only and makes no promises about future policy. In contrast, Odyssean
guidancethe phrase is motivated by Odysseus’s decision to tie himself to the mast to be able to
resist the calls of the Sirensis intended to pre-commit the central bank to some (possibly
contingent) set of future policies.
The goals of Delphic and Odyssean guidance are different. Delphic guidanceas for
example seen in the Fed’s famous “dot plot,” which shows the interest-rate forecasts of
individual FOMC participantsis designed primarily to help the public and market participants
understand the committee’s outlook, reaction function, and policy plans. More informally,
central bankers’ public remarks about the likely course of the economy and policy are usually
Delphic in intent. Increasingly, central banks are incorporating Delphic guidance into their
communication strategy during normal times; this development primarily reflects trends to
increased transparency by central banks, rather than the emergence of the ZLB as an important
6
policy constraint. By improving the clarity of the central bank communication, Delphic
guidance is intended to increase the predictability of monetary policy and make it more effective.
Odyssean guidance, in contrast, is most likely to be relevant when the policy rate is at or
close to the ZLB, so that the scope for short-term rate cuts is limited. Typically, monetary
policymakers use Odyssean guidance to communicate a promise to keep rates lower for longer
than implied by their normal reaction function. If the promise is credible, then market
participants should bid down longer-term yields and bid up asset prices today, effectively adding
stimulus despite the ZLB constraint. The key word here is “commitment.” If prior commitment
were impossible, for the reasons explored in the time-consistency literature (Kydland and
Prescott, 1977), then Odyssean forward guidance could not materially change market
expectations and would consequently be useless. In practice, central bank guidance does appear
to have significant effects on asset prices (Campbell et al., 2012; Swanson, 2017) and thus,
presumably, on the economy. Central bankers’ concerns for their own reputations and those of
their institutions, as well as the tendency of market participants to look for focal points around
which expectations can coalesce, appear in practice to provide monetary policymakers some
ability to commit to future policy actions.
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), the Fed’s policymaking body, provided
regular forward guidance during the recovery from the crisis. Some controversy has arisen about
the FOMC’s approach. Michael Woodford (2009) and others have argued that the FOMC
inappropriately used Delphic rather than Odyssean formulations in its guidance, limiting its
benefit. For example, at the same meeting at which the policy rate was cut effectively to zero,
the December 2008 FOMC statement indicated, “…the Committee anticipates that weak
economic conditions are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels of the federal funds rate for
some time (FOMC, 2008). By speaking of “anticipating” or “expecting” rates to remain low,
rather than using stronger language of commitment or intention, Woodford argues, the FOMC
created less stimulus than it might have. Indeed, by signaling pessimism about the outlook, the
FOMC’s guidance (in Woodford’s view) might have been counterproductive.
Woodford is right in principle, and all else equal, a policy committee whose intent is to
provide Odyssean guidance should try to make its commitments as clear and as nearly ironclad
as possible. A real-world complication is that policy committees are not typically unitary actors,
but may include participants of diverse views, trying to reach compromise in an uncertain
7
environment. Some hedging or ambiguity in the committee’s official statements may therefore
be difficult to avoid. In practice, however, the FOMC’s guidance after the crisisas mediated
by the public comments of policymakersdid seem to have Odyssean effects. Notably, the
Fed’s introduction of forward guidance was typically followed by changes in longer-term interest
rates, exchange rates, and equity prices consistent with substantial increases in monetary
accommodation (Femia et al., 2013; Swanson, 2017) and by reduced sensitivity of near-term rate
expectations to economic news (Williams, 2014). The increases in equity prices in particular
suggested that markets were focused on the FOMC’s signal of greater policy patience (the
Odyssean aspect) rather than on an indication of greater pessimism (Delphic). Moreover,
professional forecasters reacted to FOMC guidance by repeatedly marking down the
unemployment rate they expected to prevail at the time that the Committee began to lift the funds
rate away from zero, implying a perceived shift in the Fed’s expected reaction function
(Bernanke, 2012; Femia et al., 2013). The apparent success of the FOMC’s guidance, developed
on the fly, is promising for the future use of verbal interventions. As both central bankers and
market participants gain experience with forward guidance, the tool should become increasingly
effective.
Another important distinction is between qualitative guidance (“considerable period”)
and quantitative guidance, for example, describing specific economic conditions that would lead
to a change in policy. Over the years, Fed guidance has evolved from qualitative towards
quantitative, reflecting the desire to enhance transparency as well as the imperative of adding
substantial accommodation during the ZLB period. Economic logic suggests that quantitative
guidance will be more effective, because it is both more precise and more verifiable ex post (and
thus easier to support by reputational concerns). However, again, a policy committee may not
always be able to agree on quantitative guidance. It may also be the case that uncertainty about
the economic situation favors the relative ambiguity of a qualitative formulation, at least initially.
Experience suggest though that qualitative guidance, if maintained for a while, often morphs into
quantitative guidance, as market participants, legislative committees, and other stakeholders
press policymakers to clarify the meaning of key phrases.
Yet another dimension of forward guidance is time-dependency versus state-dependency.
The FOMC used both types after the crisis, indicating first that it expected to hold rates low
through a certain date, then tying rate increases to thresholds based on the prevailing
8
unemployment and inflation rates.
2
In principle, policy settings should depend on the state of the
economy, and so state-dependent guidance should be the default in the future (Feroli et al.,
2016).
3
As pointed out by Williams (2016) however, date-based guidance may at times be more
effective, perhaps because it is more definitive and more credible to market participants. A
particular situation in which date-based guidance might be desirable arises when policymakers
and the market have different economic outlooks. Suppose the ideal guidance would hold rates
at zero at least until unemployment fell to 6 percent; but suppose also that market participants
expect unemployment to reach 6 percent in one year while policymakers believe that
unemployment will decline more slowly, reaching 6 percent in two years. In that case, state-
dependent guidance would be insufficiently stimulative from the policymakers’ point of view,
and time-dependent guidance (a promise that rates will remain low for two years) would achieve
a greater reduction in current long-term rates and be more consistent with the policymakers’
objectives.
I’ve been discussing forward guidance about rates, but guidance can be provided about
aspects of policy other than rates, notably, about plans for asset purchases. Such guidance is a
natural extension of rate guidance and can be Delphic or Odyssean in intent. The main point
here is that guidance about the components of policy needs to be carefully coordinated, so that
the planned sequencing of policy changes is clear. For example, the famous 2013 “taper
tantrum” followed Fed guidance that it anticipated reducing the pace of its asset purchases,
conditional on economic developments. However, the tantrum reflected not so much the
expectation of reduced asset purchases per se, but rather the inference in some quarters of the
market (as could be seen in futures quotes) that increases in short-term rates would quickly
follow the slowing of asset purchases. (See below for more on the “signaling” aspects of
quantitative easing.) Fed policymakers had communicated their intention to keep rates low for a
long time after the end of asset purchases, but evidently those promises had not sunk in, and
2
The FOMC experimented with three variations of qualitative forward guidance in December 2008, March 2009,
and November 2009. In August 2011, January 2012 and September 2012, the FOMC used different versions of
calendar-based forward guidance in which they set a date in which they would keep rates ‘exceptionally low’. In
December 2012 the FOMC switched to a state-dependent form of forward guidance in which they committed to
keeping interest rates ‘exceptionally low’ at least as long as the unemployment rate was above 6.5%, inflation was
below 2.5% based on one to two year ahead forecasts, and inflation expectations remained anchored.
3
In principle, optimal policy depends not only on the current state of the economy but on its history as well. I
discuss this point further below.
9
coordinated reiterations of the point had to be made before market expectations re-adjusted and
market conditions calmed.
A final observation on forward guidance: In this section I have been treating guidance,
particularly of the Odyssean variety, as an ad hoc intervention, a supplement to management of
the short-term rate. Alternatively, or in addition, the central bank could adopt an overarching
framework that implies systematic Odyssean responses to ZLB episodes. I’ll explore this
possibility below, in the section on policy frameworks.
Quantitative easing
Probably the most controversial form of unconventional policy adopted in recent years
was what the Federal Reserve called large-scale asset purchases (LSAPs) but most of the rest of
the world persisted in calling “quantitative easing”, or QE.
4
The Federal Reserve engaged in
three rounds of QE, during which its balance sheet expanded from less than a trillion dollars to
$4.5 trillion. The Bank of England, European Central Bank, Swedish Riksbank, and Bank of
Japan (which had pioneered asset purchases as a form of monetary policy well before the crisis)
have also undertaken quantitative easing.
Quantitative easing involves central bank purchases of securities in the open market,
financed by the creation of bank reserves held at the central bank. By law, the Fed was able to
purchase only Treasury securities and mortgage-related securities issued by government-
sponsored enterprises. Other central banks, in contrast, have been able to buy a range of private
securities, including corporate bonds and equities. The limits on the Fed did not seem to prevent
its version of QE from being effective, although it was perhaps fortunate that, following a crisis
centered on housing finance, the law did permit Fed purchases of mortgage-related securities.
Research suggests that QE works through two principal channels, the signaling channel
and the portfolio balance channel. The signaling channel arises to the extent that asset purchases
serve to demonstrate the central bank’s commitment to monetary easing, and in particular to
keeping short-term rates lower for longer (Bauer and Rudebusch, 2013). As discussed above, the
so-called taper tantrum in 2013 demonstrated the practical relevance of the signaling channel of
4
I also tried, without success, to name the program “credit easing,” to distinguish it from the Bank of Japan’s earlier
foray into asset purchases (Bernanke, 2009). I argued that “credit easing” focused on removing duration from bond
markets, in contrast to BOJ-style quantitative easing, which had the primary goal and metric of increasing the high-
powered money stock.
10
QE. As noted, because of the importance of the signaling channel, it is essential that asset
purchases and interest rate policy be closely integrated, and that in particular the central bank be
clear about its planned sequencing of the introduction and withdrawal of its various tools.
The portfolio balance channel depends on the premise that securities are imperfect
substitutes in investors’ portfolios, reflecting differences in liquidity, transactions costs,
information, regulatory restrictions, and the like. Imperfect substitutability implies that changes
in the net supply of a security affect asset prices and yields, as investors must be induced to
rebalance their portfolios (Bonis et al., 2017). In principle, the two channels of QE can be
distinguished by the fact that the signaling channel operates by affecting expectations of future
policy rates while the portfolio balance channel works by changing term and risk premiums.
There have been many studies of the effectiveness of QE, mostly through event studies of
the impact of QE announcements on interest rates and asset prices; for surveys, see, e.g., Gagnon
(2016b), Bhattarai and Neely (2016), and Williams (2014). There is not a large sample of QE
programs to study, and econometric identification of the unexpected (and thus not fully
discounted) components of QE announcements is difficult. Consequently, disagreements remain
among researchers about the magnitude and persistence of QE effects and about the relative
importance of the two primary channels of effect. Nevertheless, the strong view that QE is
ineffective has been pretty decisively rejected. There appears instead to be a broad consensus
that QE has proven a useful tool, with demonstrable effects on financial conditions.
5
QE has
been found to have significant effects on both rate expectations and term premiums, suggesting
that both the signaling and portfolio balance channels are operative (Bauer & Rudebusch, 2013:
Huther et al., 2017). And, although showing direct links to macroeconomic outcomes is not
straightforward, the experiences of the U.S., U.K. Japan, and Europe all suggest that the use of
large-scale QE has been followed, over the subsequent couple of years, by strengthening
aggregate demand and improved economic performance (Engen et al., 2015).
6
5
For example, Gagnon (2016b), Table 1, reports 18 estimates from 16 studies of the effects of QE bond purchases
on bond yields. For U.S. data, the median effect of a hypothetical program sized at 10 percent of GDP on 10-year
yields is 82 basis points. Using the conventional rule of thumb that a 10 basis point reduction in the 10-year yield is
about equivalent to a 25 basis point cut in the federal funds, that’s roughly equal to 200 basis points of funds rate
reductions for a program of that size. (The Fed’s program was considerably larger than 10 percent of GDP.)
According to Gagnon’s survey, the median effect of purchases programs on the term premium component of 10-year
yields only is 44 basis points, suggesting that both signaling effects and portfolio balance effects operate.
6
It is true that QE has not been sufficient in a number of those cases to return inflation to target. However, the weak
link in the causal chain appears to be in the influence of declining slack on inflation, not the effect of monetary
11
Controversies about QE have focused less on whether the medicine works and more on
the possible side effects. Many dark warnings accompanied the introduction of QE programs by
major central banks after the financial crisis. In a memorable example, the Republican
leadership of the U.S. Congress wrote to the Fed in November 2010 to express concerns about
further asset purchases. Their letter argued that “such a measure introduces significant
uncertainty regarding the future strength of the dollar and could result both in hard-to-control
long-term inflation and potentially generate artificial [sic] asset bubbles that could cause further
economic disruptions (Herszenhorn, 2010). The Congressional leaders also were worried about
foreign criticism of the Fed’s actions, noting that “any action….that impairs U.S. trade relations
at a time when we should be fighting global trade protection measures will only further harm the
global economy and could delay recovery in the United States.” As the legislators noted, there
was indeed foreign criticism of Fed plans for more QE, including from Brazilian finance minister
Guido Mantega, who argued that the Fed’s actions presaged a “currency war”, and German
finance minister Wolfgang Schauble, who reportedly called the policy “clueless (Garnham &
Wheatley, 2010; Atkins, 2010). A subsequent letter from conservative economists and market
participants echoed the themes of the Congressional letter, warning against “currency
debasement and inflation” and adding that QE could “distort financial markets and greatly
complicate future Fed efforts to normalize monetary policy (Wall Street Journal, 2010). Less
well remembered is that, in September 2011 the Republican Congressional leadership wrote a
similar, follow-up letter, adding the concern that QE could “promote borrowing by
overleveraged consumers (Wall Street Journal, 2011). Of course, these themes were staples of
Wall Street Journal and Financial Times op-eds throughout the period.
7
I think it’s fair to say that these warnings, and many more like them, have not proved
prescient. Certainly there has been no massive upsurge in inflationquite the opposite, of
courseor a collapse in the dollar, as predicted by proponents of crude monetarism (of a type,
certainly, that Milton Friedman would never have endorsed). Without a sustained decline in the
dollar, and with a stronger U.S. economy providing increased demand for imports, Mantega’s
concern about a currency war also proved baseless. Household leverage has not risen as the
policy (including QE) on aggregate demand. The apparent flatness (or downward shift) of the Phillips curve is a
problem for any macroeconomic policy aimed at raising inflation.
7
See for example Taylor and Ryan (2010).
12
second Congressional letter predicted; indeed, household debt and interest burdens have fallen
significantly since the crisis.
Concerns about asset bubbles have been especially persistent (although these would
appear to relate more to accommodative monetary policies in general than to QE in particular).
To be clear, there is no doubt that monetary policy affects the prices of stocks and other assets;
indeed, those effects are an important vehicle of monetary transmission. The intended effects of
monetary easing on asset prices work through fundamentals, including the reduced discounting
of future returns implied by lower interest rates, expectations of stronger economic performance,
and moderate increases in risk-bearing capacity. Asset price increases due to those fundamental
causes are desirable and pose no significant risks to economic or financial stability. Concern
about bubbles is therefore properly focused on asset price increases that significantly exceed
what can be justified by fundamentals. Claims that QE has generated asset bubbles in this
relevant sense are difficult or impossible to disprove; and, of course, at some point there will
inevitably be a downward correction in asset prices, as has happened periodically in the past.
However, it’s been seven years since the first Congressional letter, and the Fed stopped
purchasing securities three years ago (although other central banks have continued it), so if QE
has generated bubble dynamics we can at least conclude that some pretty long lags are involved.
What about other critiques? The claim that QE “distorts” financial markets, raised in the
letter from economists and market participants, is heard fairly often. It’s not clear exactly what
that means. The goal of QE, and of monetary policy generally, is to set financial conditions
consistent with full employment and stable prices, which can be thought of as trying to undo the
economic distortions arising from price and wage stickiness, monopolistic competition, credit
market frictions, and the like. In this respect appropriate monetary policy is “un-distorting;” in
particular, allocations under active monetary policy should be closer rather than further from the
competitive, free-market, flexible-price ideal.
A possible rationalization of the “distortion” claim is that QE works, at least in part, by
affecting term premiums (and through them, the whole gamut of asset prices). From a market
participant’s point of view, when QE is active it feels as if government (central bank) decisions,
rather than private-sector fundamentals, are setting asset prices. Moreover, in such situations it
may appear that the highest returns go to the best Fed-watchers, rather than to those whose
expertise is in evaluating economic fundamentals. Some frustration with this state of affairs on
13
the part of professional investors is understandable. Note, though, that QE affects term premiums
by affecting the net maturity distribution of government debt held by the private sector. In this
respect, a QE programwhich amounts to a replacement of longer-term government obligations
in private hands with shorter-term obligations (bank reserves, in the case of QE)is not
fundamentally different from a change in the maturity structure of debt issued by the Treasury.
That government decisions about the maturity structure of its debt would affect term premiums
seems natural and, since the government has to choose some maturity distribution, it’s not clear
what it would mean for government policy to be “neutral” with respect to the term premium
(Greenwood et al., 2014). In short, there is no such thing as an “undistorted” value of the term
premium, not so long as the mix of outstanding government liabilities is relevant to asset pricing.
A possible response to this point is that at least Treasury maturity decisions are largely
non-responsive to short-term economic conditions, with issuance policies generally being
smooth and set well in advance. In contrast, Fed QE programs are typically large in size and less
predictable, responding to economic developments and (importantly) to how monetary
policymakers choose to interpret those developments. To the extent that Fed decisions are hard
to forecast, even conditional on the outlook, they add noise to asset prices. But of course that is
true for any form of monetary policy. I think it comes down to whether Fed policy, inclusive of
policy errors and misjudgments, is economically stabilizing on net, or not. If it is stabilizing,
then though the unpredictable components of Fed policy and communication may be a nuisance
for market participants, overall monetary policy (including QE) reduces rather than increases the
overall level of distortions in the economy.
8
Another common critique of QE is that it purportedly promotes increased inequality,
primarily because of its effects on the prices of stocks and other assets. This claim is
questionable on its face (Bernanke, 2015; Bivens, 2015). Empirically, it is far from obvious that
QE (or easy money generally) worsens inequality in any meaningful way, once all the diverse
effects of policy are taken into account. It is of course true that, all else equal, higher stock
prices mean greater inequality of wealthalthough the effect on income inequality is mitigated
by the fact that easy money also lowers the rate of return on assets, so that income from capital
8
As James Tobin (1977) once said, “It takes a heap of Harberger triangles to fill an Okun gap.” Translated from
economist, this aphorism suggests that distortions at the microeconomic level are hardly of consequence when the
economy as a whole is operating far from its potential. The goal of monetary policy is to close Okun gaps.
14
rises by less than the rise in asset values.
9
However, QE also yields gains in income and wealth
that are more broadly based, including 1) positive effects on house prices, the principal asset of
the middle class; 2) the benefits of lower interest rates and higher prices for debtors, including
homeowners able to refinance to lower payments; 3) the savings for taxpayers of lower
government borrowing costs and (possibly) increased seigniorage; and 4) most importantly, the
effects of monetary accommodation on jobs, wages, and incomes (Bivens, 2015; Engen et al.,
2015). It’s revealing that in public debates, advocates for workerslike the group Fed Up,
which met with FOMC members in Jackson Hole in 2016have tended to favor the
continuation of easy money, while the typical op-ed about the adverse effects of easy money on
the distribution of income and wealth is written by a hedge fund manager, banker, or right-wing
politicianpeople who have otherwise not traditionally exhibited much concern about inequality
(Fleming, 2016). That political alignmentworkers’ groups in support of easy money,
financiers in favor of higher interest ratesis of course the historical pattern in the United States,
going back to William Jennings Bryan and beyond.
In any case, whatever effects monetary policy has on inequality are likely to be transient,
in contrast to the secular forces of technology and globalization that have contributed to the
multi-decade rise in inequality in the United States and some other advanced economies. If the
monetary effects on inequality are modest (indeed, of indeterminate sign) and mostly temporary,
as seems most likely, then it makes sense for monetary policymakers to ignore distributional
effects and to focus on their legal mandate to promote price stability and full employment,
leaving distributional concerns be addressed by other policies, including fiscal policy. If, on the
other hand, the effects of monetary policy on inequality are not transient, then presumably the
reason is what economists have called hysteresis, the idea that a “hot” economy promotes higher
long-term growth by promoting labor force participation, higher skills, and higher wages.
However, the presence of significant hysteresis effects would likely imply that easy money
during periods of economic weakness reduces inequality, rather than the reverse.
A final criticism of QE is that it exposes the central bank to capital losses, in the event
that longer-term interest rates rise unexpectedly quickly. Although central banks don’t have to
mark to market, and they can operate perfectly well with negative capital, losses on their asset
9
Hence the apparently contradictory claims that QE both helps wealth-holders and hurts savers; see Bernanke
(2015) for a discussion.
15
holdings would ultimately be reflected in reduced seigniorage payments to the treasury. Central
banks naturally see this outcome as a political risk to their independence and institutional
reputations which, all else equal, may make them more hesitant to use QE. However, political
risk to the central bank is not equivalent to a loss in social welfare. From the perspective of
society as a whole, the fiscal risks of QE have to be balanced against the substantial benefits of a
tool that gives monetary policymakers additional scope to respond to a serious economic
downturn or to unwanted disinflation.
Moreover, the fiscal risks of QE are not one-sided. QE programs can be quite profitable
for the central bank and the Treasury, because on average the yields on the longer-term assets the
central bank acquires are higher than those on its short-term liabilities, and because declining
yields create capital gains on the central bank’s existing bond holdings. Since 2009, the Federal
Reserve has remitted more than $650 billion in profits to the U.S. Treasury (Federal Reserve,
2017), a much higher rate of remittances than usual before the crisis. On the other hand, if fiscal
losses do occur as the result of a QE program, it will likely be because the economy recovered
more quickly and strongly than expected, resulting in higher interest rates; since losses are most
likely to occur at times when the economy is unexpectedly strong, they are hedged, from a social
perspective. Finally, and importantly, the beneficial fiscal effects of an effective QE program go
well beyond seigniorage, as the government’s budget also benefits from low borrowing rates,
avoidance of deflation or very low inflation, and the higher revenues that result from increased
economic activity.
All that said, the fiscal argument seems to me to be more balanced than some of the other
criticisms of QE. There are difficult governance issues and competing values in play here, and
people could reasonably come to different conclusions. One approach, similar to that taken by
the United Kingdom, is for the central bank to consult with the Treasury on QE plans. I don’t
advocate that approach because of the implied reduction in central bank independence, but I
appreciate that it may reduce the political risks associated with the use of QE.
Negative interest rates and yield curve control
I will comment briefly on two monetary tools in use outside the United States, but which
I don’t expect to be used by the Fed in the foreseeable future: negative (nominal) interest rates
and pegging longer-term interest rates (so-called yield curve control).
16
Negative interest rates have been recently employed in Japan and a number of European
countries (Bernanke, 2016a). To enforce negative rates, central banks generally charge a fee on
the reserve holdings of commercial banks. Arbitrage ensures that the negative return to reserves
translates into negative returns to other short-term liquid assets. Negative short rates need not
imply negative rates on longer-term assets, particularly those that are less liquid or involve credit
risk. Rather, negative short-term rates give the central bank a new tool for bringing down the
longer-term rates, like mortgage rates, that matter most for economic activity. The evidence
suggests that negative rates have helped to ease overall financial conditions in the countries in
which they have been used, thereby promoting economic recovery (Dell'Ariccia et al, 2017).
For economists, used to thinking about negative real interest rates, moderately negative
nominal rates are not a big deal. There is very little practical difference between a 0.1 percent
return and a return of negative 0.1 percent, for example. However, many non-economists find
the idea of negative nominal rates disorienting, a reaction that has contributed to political
resistance and on the margin has probably made central bankers more hesitant to use this tool.
Putting aside the politics, and excluding limitations on the use of currency (Rogoff, 2016) as
beyond the scope of this note, negative interest rates appear to provide relatively modest benefits
and have modest costs. So while the tool may well be appropriate and useful in some contexts, it
does not merit the overheated public attention it has received.
Under current institutional arrangements, the potential benefit of negative rates are
relatively modest because attempts to push rates too far below zero will induce substitution into
cash. The most negative rate yet imposed is minus 75 basis points, by Denmark (Danmarks,
2015). To date, negative rates have so far not triggered much movement into cash, as best as we
can tell, but it is likely that more such adjustment would occur if rates were to go much further
below zero, or if negative-rate policies were perceived to be recurring or persistent.
The costs of negative rates mostly arise from their interaction with certain institutional
features of financial markets. For example, in the United States, money market mutual funds
(MMMFs) generally guarantee a nominal return of no less than zero, and failure to meet that
standard (called “breaking the buck”) led to a run on MMMFs in 2008, after the Lehman failure.
Concerns about possible destabilization of MMMFs were an important reason that the Fed did
not employ negative rates during the post-crisis period (Burke et al., 2010). Reforms undertaken
since the crisis have reduced this risk, by forcing many money market funds that invest in private
17
assets to shift to a system of floating net asset values (which allows for a negative nominal
return) and by inducing a shift toward lower-risk government funds (SEC, 2014; Chen et al.,
2017).
A more frequently heard concern is that negative rates could decapitalize the banking
system, because banks are supposedly unable to pass negative rates on to depositors and thus
would have to absorb the loss. There is little evidence from the European or Japanese
experiences that modestly negative rates have actually hurt bank profits or bank lending. Retail
deposits are only a portion of bank funding; presumably, banks can pass on negative yields to
wholesale funders or institutional depositors. Moreover, central banks can implement negative
rates in ways that mitigate the effects on bank profits; for example, the Bank of Japan exempts a
significant portion of bank reserves from its fees, which are applied only on the margin. Overall,
there are few costs of negative rates that could not be managed over time through institutional
reform or alternative approaches to enforcing negative rates by central banks. Whether
undertaking such changes is worthwhile, given that political resistance to negative rates appears
disproportionate to their generally modest benefits, is an open question. At the Fed, there was
little support for negative rates during the post-crisis period, a situation that does not appear to
have changed.
10
Yield curve control, recently introduced by the Bank of Japan, is the targeting of yields
on longer-term bonds; e.g., the BOJ is currently targeting the yield of ten-year government bonds
at around zero. Yield curve control is “dual” to conventional QE: Instead of setting targets for
securities purchases and letting the market determine yields, as in ordinary QE, under yield curve
control the central bank targets the yield on one or more securities and adjusts its purchases as
necessary to hit the targets (Bernanke, 2002; Chaurushiya & Kuttner, 2003; Bernanke, 2016b).
Yield curve control has some potential advantages: Because yields directly affect
borrowing and investment decisions, a rate-targeting strategy affords greater precision in
estimating the amount of financial accommodation delivered than does ordinary QE. A credible
yield target may also be enforceable with reduced quantities of purchases by the central bank,
because deviations from the target will be arbitraged away by market participants. Yield curve
10
John Williams, the president of the San Francisco Fed, said in 2016 that negative interest rates “are at the bottom
of the stack in terms of net effectiveness” (Mui, 2016). However, interestingly, Chair Yellen has indicated that she
believes that the Fed has the legal authority to impose negative interest rates should it choose to do so (United
States, 2016).
18
control can also be an efficient strategy when the securities available for purchase are potentially
limited in quantity and supplied with less-than-perfect elasticity, as is the case with the Japanese
government bonds that make up the bulk of the BOJ’s purchase program. In particular, the
adoption of yield curve control by the BOJ has allowed the Japanese authorities to maintain
substantial stimulus, even as the supply of bonds available for purchase by the BOJ has shrunk
(Bernanke 2016d).
On the other hand, in jurisdictions with deep and liquid securities markets, like those for
U.S. government bonds, a rate-targeting central bank might have to buy up most of the market if
the target it set were not fully credible. A rate target for a security whose maturity exceeded the
expected duration of the targeting program would be particularly hard to enforce, as incoming
news would affect investors’ views of the time of exit from the targeting regime and of the post-
regime yield. For that reason, Fed staff considering rate-targeting strategies concluded that only
relatively short-term yieldsperhaps up to a couple of yearscould be fixed, potentially
limiting the utility of the program (Bowman et al., 2010; Bernanke 2016b). An intriguing
possibility, however, is that a relatively short-horizon peg could be used to complement forward
guidance about future short rates.
11
Policy sequencing
What policy tools will be used, and in what sequence, when the next recession hits?
Yellen (2016) has described the Fed’s prospective toolbox. In the face of an economic
slowdown, the FOMC would respond first with conventional rate cuts. In an environment of
super-abundant bank reserves, in practice that would involve reductions in the Fed’s key
administered rates, including the interest rate paid to banks on excess reserves, the rate offered to
money market funds and others on overnight reverse repurchase agreements, and the lending rate
at the discount window. Current thinking is that, when the ZLB looms, rate cuts should be
aggressive (no “saving ammunition”); see Reifschneider and Williams (2000). However, in
practice, uncertainty about the state of the economy might lead the Fed to put off decisive action
until the situation becomes clearer.
11
For example, a promise to keep rates low for two years would be reinforced by a commitment to peg yields out to
a date two years from the announcement. This strategy would be difficult to implement for state-dependent (as
opposed to time-dependent) guidance, however.
19
Forward guidance, of the Odyssean variety, would come next (substantial Delphic
guidance is already in place). Relative to earlier experience, I would expect a much earlier
adoption of state-contingent, quantitative commitments to hold rates low.
What about QE? Fed policymakers have been clear that QE is now part of the toolkit and
that it would be used if necessary (United States, 2017; FOMC, 2017). I am sure that’s true, but
I would not be surprised if there is a period of hesitation before the FOMC starts up new rounds
of asset purchases. The effects of QE on financial markets and the economy are less well
understood and less precisely estimated than those of more-conventional policies. QE’s effects
likely vary over time, depending for example on whether financial markets are stressed or
operating normally. Moreover, because some significant part of its power comes through
signaling effects, QE is also a difficult tool to use in a continuous, gradated manner. I expect
that QE will be used only occasionally in the future, during more severe downturns, and then
typically in large discrete chunks.
Speaking positively rather than normatively, I don’t see much likelihood that negative
rates or yield curve control will be employed in the United States in the foreseeable future,
unless circumstances become dire. Given current institutional arrangements, negative rates have
only modest benefits and may create problems for some financial institutions. Targeting longer-
term interest rates, at least at maturities out beyond a couple of years, could be a hazardous
undertaking given the deep and liquid markets for U.S. government obligations. It is not
inconceivable though that the Fed might consider targeting yields at somewhat shorter horizons,
particularly as a way of reinforcing its forward guidance on rates.
DEFEATING THE ZLB: THE POLICY FRAMEWORK
As discussed in the previous section, the Fed and other central banks retain a number of
effective monetary tools, even if the current low level of neutral rates persists. In particular, the
experience gained in recent years with forward guidance, quantitative easing, and (in some
jurisdictions) negative interest rates should at least partly compensate for the reduced scope for
conventional rate cuts. We should also not ignore the countercyclical potential of fiscal policy.
Political and ideological constraints, as well as constraints on fiscal space in some jurisdictions,
limit the flexibility and timeliness of fiscal tools; that’s why monetary policy has normally been
the first line of defense against short-term economic instability. But recent experience suggests
20
that fiscal policy can provide some backstop in the most severe slowdowns, as in the United
States in 2008 and 2009 (Matthews, 2011; Auerbach and Gorodnichenko, 2017).
All that said, I am less sanguine than Yellen (2016) that the current monetary toolbox
would prove sufficient to address a sharp downturn. In particular, there is no guarantee that the
next recessionary shock will occur only when policy rates are at or above neutral levels. If the
Fed had to react to a new slowdown today, it would have only 100 basis points or so of room to
cut short rates, and other major central banks (such as the ECB and BOJ, whose short rates are
already negative) would have virtually no room to cut, even at the long end of the curve. I am
consequently sympathetic to the view of Williams (2017) and others that we should be thinking
now about what can be done to enhance the potency of monetary policy. In this section I’ll
discuss some recent proposals to improve the effectiveness of monetary policy by changing the
policy target/framework. I’ll focus here on two leading options: raising the inflation target and
switching to a price level target.
12
After discussing some pros and cons of these two leading
options, I’ll suggest a compromise approach.
As noted, one proposal for modifying the policy framework is to keep the current
inflation targeting framework of the Fed and other major central banks, but to raise the level of
the targetfrom 2 percent or so to 3 or even 4 percent. Presumably, after a period of transition,
an increase in the inflation target would result in a comparable increase in nominal interest rates.
Higher nominal rates would in turn expand the scope for short-term rate cuts and reduce the
salience of the zero lower bound at all points of the yield curve.
13
Most recently, a group of
economists signed a letter to the Fed arguing for a higher inflation target, and the aforementioned
Fed Up group held a seminar at this year’s Jackson Hole conference endorsing the idea (Baker et
al., 2017; Leubsdorf, 2017).
As a measure to increase the potency of monetary policy, raising the inflation target has
some advantages: It’s a straightforward step, one that should be easy to communicate and
explain, and it would allow the Fed and other major central banks to stay within their established
12
An option that deserves further study, but which I don’t have space to discuss here, is nominal GDP targeting. A
practical issue with this approach is that measurements of nominal GDP are not as timely as those of inflation and
unemployment, and more subject to revision.
13
Should the increase be to 3 percent or 4 percent? The literature offers limited guidance (Diercks, 2017). An
increase to 4 percent provides more room for future rate cuts, but it might be difficult to defend 4 percent inflation as
being consistent with central bank mandates for price stability. An increase to 3 percent adds only modest scope for
rate cuts; if that is the increase contemplated, it would be desirable to compare the costs and benefits of that increase
with the adoption of negative rates, which add similar amounts of policy space (Bernanke 2016c).
21
policy frameworks. These are important benefits. At the same time, I see some problems with
this proposal:
First, proponents may be underestimating the costs, uncertainties, and delays associated
with the transition to a higher target. We have seen, most recently in Japan, that managing
inflation expectations through central bank announcements can be tricky. Given that inflation
expectations in advanced economies seem well anchored at two percent or below, trying to raise
expectations and to re-anchor them at a higher level could well be a protracted and uncertain
process, with side effects including financial volatility and increases in risk premiums. (Inflation
uncertainty would be particularly challenging for bond markets, where investors would be
simultaneously skeptical of the central bank’s statements and fearful of capital losses.) If
inflation expectations were to remain sticky near current levels, then the Fed would have to
demonstrate its commitment to the higher target by intentionally overheating the economy for an
extended period. It’s possible that sustained overheating could have beneficial effectsthrough
hysteresis channels, for examplebut it might also prove to be destabilizing and difficult to
manage, particularly if inflation expectations became volatile.
Second, to be fully effective in raising longer-term nominal yields, the increase in the
inflation target must be perceived as permanent and irrevocable. However, that perception
would be undermined by the apparent willingness of the Fed to raise its target for what might
appear to be tactical reasons. Looking forward, it is likely that the determinants of the “optimal”
inflation targetsuch as the prevailing equilibrium real interest rate, the costs of inflation, and
aspects of the monetary transmission mechanismwill change over time. If the Fed raised its
inflation target today based primarily on the low level of real interest rates, would it change the
target again in response to future changes in fundamentals? That would be important to clarify
when making the first change to the target, but it is not an easy matter on which to commit, since
the membership of the policy committee and the state of knowledge about monetary policy and
the economy both change over time.
Third, although quantifying the economic costs of inflation has proved difficult, we know
that inflation is very unpopular with the public. This unpopularity may be due to reasons that
economists find unpersuasivevarious forms of money illusion, for example. Or perhaps the
public perceives costs of inflationthe greater difficulty of planning and calculation when
inflation is high, for example—that economic models don’t well capture. In any case, it’s not a
22
coincidence that the promotion of “price stability” is a key part of the mandate of the Fed and
most other central banks. Certainly, a substantial increase in targeted inflation would invite a
backlash, perhaps even a legal challenge. Proponents have suggested convening a national
commission to approve the increase in the inflation target, to increase its legitimacy and
durability. Those proponents should be careful what they wish for. In the United States, rather
than validating a higher inflation target to afford scope for discretionary monetary policy, I
suspect that the political process would be more likely instead to reaffirm the centrality of “price
stability” and possibly even eliminate the “maximum employment” component of the Fed’s dual
mandate. Even if the political process supported the higher target in the first instance, market
participants would put some weight on a future reversal, undermining the target’s credibility.
Fourth, and importantly, we know from a great deal of insightful theoretical work that an
increase in the inflation target is an inferior response to the problems created by the ZLB
(Krugman, 1998; Woodford and Eggertsson, 2003; Werning, 2011). Rather, the theoretically
preferred response is for the central bank to promise to follow a “make-up” policy (or, in
Woodford’s term, for policy to be “history-dependent). Specifically, suppose the ZLB binds for
a period, keeping monetary policy tighter than it otherwise would have been. Then (speaking
very loosely) the optimal policy involves the central bank promising to keep rates lower for
longer than it otherwise would have, where the length of the “make-up” period increases with the
severity of the episode and the cumulative shortfall in monetary ease. If the public understands
and believes this promise, then the expectation of easier policy and more rapid growth in the
future should act to mitigate declines in output and inflation during the period in which the ZLB
is binding. Note, by the way, the close analogy to Odyssean forward guidance, discussed earlier.
The difference is that, rather than being implemented by ad hoc guidance, the optimal policy is
conceptualized as part of the central bank’s permanent policy framework, about which the public
is supposed to learn over time.
In comparison to this theoretically optimal policy, an increase in the inflation target is
inefficient in at least two respects. First, as Woodford (2009) has pointed out, it forces society to
bear the costs of higher inflation at all times, whereas under the optimal policy, inflation should
rise only temporarily, following ZLB episodes. Second, a one-time increase in the inflation
target does not optimally calibrate the vigor of the policy response to a given ZLB episode to the
duration or severity of the episode.
23
A somewhat better option than raising the inflation target is to adopt a price level target,
an approach advocated by a number of economists and policymakers (Svensson, 1999; Gaspar et
al., 2007; Williams, 2017). Effectively, a price-level targeting central bank tries to keep the long-
run average inflation rate close to a targeted value, say 2 percent. The principal difference
between price-level targeting and conventional inflation targeting is the treatment of “bygones.”
An inflation-targeting central bank aims to keep inflation stationary around its target, an
approach that allows policymakers to “look through” a temporary change in the inflation rate, so
long as inflation returns to target after a time. A price-level targeter, by contrast, commits to
reversing temporary deviations of inflation from target, by following a temporary surge in
inflation with a period of inflation below target; and, likewise, following an episode of low
inflation with a period of inflation above target. Importantly, both inflation targeters and price-
level targeters can be “flexible.” That is, they can take output and employment considerations
into account, in that the speed at which they return to target can depend (and in formal models,
usually optimally depends) on the state of the real economy.
14
In this section I consider only
“flexible” variants of policy rules.
Switching to a price level target has at least two principal advantages over raising the
inflation target. The first is that price-level targeting is consistent with low average inflation
(say, 2 percent) over time and thus with the price stability mandate. Indeed, price-level targeting
arguably promotes price stability better than does inflation targeting, because its commitment to
stabilizing long-run average inflation should lead to considerably less uncertainty about the level
of prices far in the future. The second advantage is that price-level targeting has the desirable
“make-up” feature of the theoretically optimal monetary policy. In particular, under price-level
targeting, periods of below-target inflation (as is likely to happen when interest rates are stuck at
their ZLB) are followed by periods in which the central bank shoots for inflation above target,
leading to “lower for longer” rate-setting.
Adopting a price level target seems preferable to raising the inflation target, but this
strategy too is not without its drawbacks. It would amount to a significant change in the central
bank’s policy framework and reaction function, and it is hard to judge how difficult it would be
to get the public and markets to understand and accept the new approach. In particular,
14
Erceg, Kiley, and Lopez-Salido (2011) show that strict price-level targeting, which ignores fluctuations in output
and employment, does not perform well.
24
switching from the inflation concept to the price level concept might require considerable
education and explanation by policymakers. How quickly, for example, would markets and the
public adjust to the implication of price-level targeting that a burst of inflation today should lead
them rationally to expect lower-than-normal inflation in the future?
Another possible concern about price-level targeting is that the “bygones are not
bygones” aspect of this approach is a two-edged sword. Under price-level targeting, the central
bank cannot “look through” supply shocks that temporarily drive up inflation, but must commit
to tightening policy in order to reverse the effects of the shock on the price level. This reversal
could be gradual and responsive to real-side conditions, as indeed the theory suggests it should
be, but it would nevertheless imply a possibly painful tightening even as the supply shock
depresses employment and output. Although a once-and-for-all commitment to such an
approach is theoretically optimal (under full credibility), in practice the commitment to reverse
the effect of supply shocks by engineering a period of below-target inflation might not be
credible; if not, efforts to offset positive inflation shocks would likely be costly.
Is there a compromise approach? One possibility, that I will describe briefly here, is to
apply a price level target and the associated “make-up” principle only to periods around ZLB
episodes, retaining the inflation-targeting framework and the current 2 percent target at other
times. As I will explain, the central bank can explain this combined policy in familiar inflation-
targeting terminology, which I take to be an advantage.
So, to be concrete, at some moment when the economy is away from the ZLB, suppose
the Fed were to make an announcement like the following:
(1) The FOMC has determined that it will retain its inflation-targeting framework, with a
symmetric inflation target of 2 percent. The FOMC will continue to pursue its
balanced approach to price stability and maximum employment, meaning in
particular, that the speed at which the FOMC aims to return inflation to target will
depend on the state of the labor market and the outlook for the economy.
(2) However, the FOMC recognizes that, at times, the zero lower bound on the federal
funds rate may prevent it from reaching its inflation and employment goals, even with
the use of unconventional monetary tools. The Committee agrees that, in future
situations in which the funds rate is at or near zero, a necessary condition for raising
the funds rate will be that average inflation since the date at which the funds rate first
25
hit zero be at least 2 percent. Beyond this necessary condition, in deciding whether to
raise the funds rate from zero, the Committee will consider the outlook for the labor
market and whether the return of inflation to target appears sustainable.
The figures below illustrate the necessary condition above as it might have been applied
to the recent ZLB episode. To be clear, nothing in this illustration should be taken as a
commentary on current Fed policy. I am considering instead a counterfactual world in which the
announcement above had been made, and internalized by markets, prior to 2008. In that
counterfactual world, it would be important for the Fed to follow through on that commitment.
However, in reality, no such commitment was made, of course, and actual policy today is not
constrained by earlier promises.
Figure 1 shows the behavior of (core PCE) inflation since 2008 Q4, the quarter in which
the federal funds rate first reached zero, or effectively zero. (I assume for this illustration that
the FOMC relies on the core inflation measure, excluding food and energy prices, to better
capture the underlying inflation trend.) As the figure shows, since 2008, inflation has been
below the 2 percent target most of the time. Figure 2 shows the cumulative, annualized inflation
rateroughly, the average inflation ratefrom 2008 Q4 to the present. Consistent with Figure
1, the average inflation rate since 2008 Q4 is also below 2 percent, by about a half percent. As
average inflation since the beginning of the ZLB period is below the 2 percent target, by the
criterion in paragraph #2 above, the FOMC would not have yet lifted the federal funds rate from
zero. Again, I am using the recent episode to illustrate my suggested rule, not to make a
recommendation about what the FOMC should do now. Note though, that if this policy rule had
been in place prior to 2008, and if it had been understood and anticipated by markets, then
longer-term yields would likely have been lower and the effective degree of policy
accommodation during the past decade might have been significantly greater. In that
counterfactual world, inflation might have been higher and the average-inflation criterion might
have already been met. This is because the Fed would have already communicated their intention
to be more accommodative going into the ZLB episode.
26
The average-inflation criterion, in (2) above, is couched in the language of inflation
targeting, which I take to be an advantage from a communications perspective. My readers will
recognize, though, that the average-inflation criterion is equivalent to a temporary price-level
target, which applies only during the ZLB episode. Expressing this in terms of the price level,
0.00%
0.50%
1.00%
1.50%
2.00%
2.50%
Figure 1: Inflation Since 2008 Q4 (Annual Rates)
Core PCE Inflation 2% Target
Source: FRED.
0.00%
0.50%
1.00%
1.50%
2.00%
2.50%
Figure 2: Cumulative Inflation (Annualized) Since 2008 Q4
Cumlative Inflation (Core PCE) 2% Target
Note: Data shows the cumulative annualized inflation rate of the core PCE price
index since 2008 Q4.
Source: FRED, Author's calculations.
27
rather than inflation, Figure 3 below shows recent values of the (core PCE) price level, relative to
a 2 percent trend starting in 2008 Q4. (Again, 2008 Q4 is the base quarter because that’s when
the federal funds rate first reached the zero lower bound.) The necessary condition, that average
inflation over the ZLB period be at least 2 percent, is equivalent to the price level (light blue
line) returning to its trend (dark blue line). As Figure 3 suggests, a period of inflation exceeding
2 percent would be necessary to satisfy that criterion.
I should emphasize that, in my proposal and as stated in paragraph (2), meeting the
average-inflation criterion is a necessary but not sufficient condition to raise rates from the ZLB.
There are at least two additional considerations: First, monetary policymakers would want to be
sure that the average inflation condition is being met on a sustainable basis and not as the result
of a transitory shock or measurement error. Expressing the condition in terms of core rather than
headline inflation, as in the figures above, would help on that score. Second, consistent with the
concept of “flexible” targeting, policymakers would also want to factor in real economic
conditions in deciding whether it was time to raise rates. Specifically, even if the average-
inflation criterion is met, the FOMC might delay liftoff until labor market conditions are or are
expected soon to be healthy. For example, they might stipulate the additional necessary
90
95
100
105
110
115
120
Index Level, 2009=100
Figure 3: Price Level Since 2008 Q4 vs. 2% Target
Core PCE Price Index 2% Target
Note: Figure shows the core PCE price level against the target core PCE price level,
assumed to rise at a 2% annual rate since 2008 Q4. Equivalently, the target price
level is the level implied by a 2% cumulative (annualized) inflation target during the
ZLB period. Data are seasonally adjusted.
Source: FRED.
28
condition that the unemployment rate be at or below estimates of the natural or sustainable rate.
I elaborate on this point and its rationale in the Appendix.
What I have called a temporary price level target shares several advantages with an
ordinary, permanent price-level targeting regime. As already noted, it has the critical “make-up”
feature, that it delays the exit from the ZLB relative to the prescriptions of conventional policy
rules, like the Taylor (1993) rule. Moreover, the make-up period will generally be longer
following more severe ZLB episodes, thereby delivering more stimulus when it is most needed.
It’s also worth reiterating the distinction between this approach and the Odyssean forward
guidance described in the previous section. The key difference is that, under a temporary price
level target, the lower-for-longer strategy is an integral part of the policy framework and thus can
be explained (and, one hopes, anticipated by market participants) in advance of an encounter
with the ZLB. If this strategy is understood, it should serve to make encounters with the ZLB
not only shorter and less severe but also less frequent in the first place.
The temporary price level target also shares with the ordinary price level target the
benefit of preserving price stability, in contrast to the strategy of simply raising the inflation
target. In particular, under this approach, inflation during both ZLB and non-ZLB periods
should average about 2 percent.
My proposal has two potential advantages over an ordinary price level target, however.
First, it does not require a major shift in existing policy frameworks, since 1) inflation targeting
would continue to define policy away from the ZLB and 2) the temporary price-level target
could be reinterpreted as part of an inflation-targeting regime, in that, as we have seen, it
amounts to targeting the average inflation rate over the ZLB period. Second, like inflation
targeting, it avoids the need to tighten policy in the face of temporary inflation shocks away from
the ZLB.
In their recent paper on the effects of the ZLB, Kiley and Roberts (2017) propose a
“shadow rate rule,” under which the timing of the exit from the ZLB is determined by the
evolution of a (unobserved) shadow interest rate, which in turn depends on economic outcomes.
They show by via simulations of econometric models that, if understood and anticipated by
markets, the shadow rate rule could substantially eliminate the macroeconomic costs of the ZLB.
My proposal for a temporary price level target has substantial affinities with the Kiley-Roberts
rule, as applied to ZLB episodes only. A principal difference is that my proposed framework
29
would be framed in terms of macro outcomes, rather than in terms of a hypothetical shadow
interest rate. In the Appendix I develop further the linkage between the two approaches.
To summarize this section, a temporary price-level target, invoked only during ZLB
episodes, appears to have many of the benefits of ordinary price-level targeting, including the
preservation of price stability and the implication that ZLB episodes are followed by “make-up”
periods of low rates. Among its additional advantages are that it could be folded into existing
inflation-targeting regimes in a straightforward way, minimizing the need to make changes in
longstanding policy frameworks and communications practices; and that it would not require the
reversal of inflation shocks that occur away from the ZLB.
CENTRAL BANK INDEPENDENCE AND INSTITUTIONAL REFORM
Of course, monetary policy decisions are not made in a vacuum and any changes,
particularly to the framework, need to be discussed in a political and institutional context. The
future of monetary policy depends in part on the structures and powers of central banks
themselves. The political blowback from the financial crisis and the ensuing recession raises the
possibility that legislatures will impose institutional change, including additional constraints on
central bank independence. In this last section, I revisit the case for central bank independence
in a world of low inflation and interest rates.
The term “central bank independence” (CBI) is sometimes used loosely, so it’s worth
spelling out what it means in a contemporary context. In particular, in a modern pluralist
democracy, CBI does not mean full autonomy or lack of accountability for monetary
policymakers, nor does it mean that political actors have no role in influencing policy, at least
over the longer term. Although institutional details differ quite a bit across countries and
jurisdictions, I associate contemporary CBI with four elements:
First, democratically elected representatives establish the central bank’s
institutional structure, including its authorities and powers; set its broad objectives; and
appoint its leadership. For example, the Federal Reserve’s Congressional mandate is to
promote maximum employment and price stability. The Fed has an idiosyncratic structure, which
includes regional Reserve Banks with private-sector boards, but it is ultimately accountable to
the President and to the Congress, who determine the Fed’s authorities and the membership of
the Federal Reserve Board. The Fed’s monetary and lending authorities, established by the
30
Congress, are generally narrower than other advanced-economy central banksfor example,
under normal circumstances and unlike other central banks, the Fed cannot buy private-sector
assets like corporate bonds or stocks, or lend outside the banking systembut it has some
emergency powers that can be called on.
Second, elected representatives regularly review the central bank’s monetary policy
decisions and progress toward mandated goals. To facilitate effective review, the central
bank provides extensive information about its plans and policies, and in general is as
transparent as possible consistent with the effective implementation of policy. It is not a
coincidence that the global trend toward greater central bank transparency has occurred at the
same time that monetary policy has assumed a more prominent role in managing the economy.
In particular, a critical motivation for the rise of inflation targeting and similar frameworks is the
communication enhancements they bring, including the regular release of forecasts and policy
projections, as well as the accountability that is facilitated by explicit objectives. The Fed’s steps
toward increased transparency in recent years include adoption of an explicit inflation target;
releasing the forecasts, including interest-rate forecasts, of FOMC participants; and the
institution of a quarterly press conference by the chair. The FOMC also releases the minutes of
its meetings after three weeks and full transcripts with a five-year lag.
Third, subject to the system of mandated objectives and regular review and
oversight, the central bank is allowed to manage the instruments of monetary policy
without overt political interference. So, for example, the Fed manages its policy interest rate
without Congressional or executive branch intervention, so long as its policy decisions can
reasonably be seen to be in pursuit of its mandated objectives. (In economists’ parlance, the Fed
has instrument independence but not goal independence.) This operational independence is
enforced in large part by norms (in the U.S., presidential acceptance of the norm of Fed
independence has been particularly important) but also by speed bumps to intervention that are
part of the institutional design. In the Fed’s case, these speed bumps include the long,
overlapping terms of Fed governors; the fact that governors can only be discharged before the
ends of their terms for inappropriate behavior, not for policy reasons; the Fed’s budgetary
independence; the long terms and non-political appointment of Reserve Bank presidents; the
political influence of the Reserve Banks’ private-sector directors; and other factors. Notably,
though, the protections of the Fed’s independence are mostly indirect or implicit and are not
31
explicitly guarded by statute or treaty, as is the case in some other jurisdictions, including Japan,
the United Kingdom, and the euro area.
A standard description of the terms of central bank independence might end here; but I
think we should recognize that, at least in the medium term, democratically elected officials must
be able to respond to institutional deficiencies of or poor execution by the central bank.
Fourth, in the medium term, elected representatives may react to inadequate central
bank performance by changing leadership or, as necessary, through institutional reform.
A viable principal-agent relationship requires the possibility of rewards or punishments for
realized outcomes, and for the possibility that the agent’s contract itself must change in light of
changing circumstances. Thus, I don’t consider periodic changes to the structure or powers of the
central bank to be necessarily inconsistent with CBI, unless the reform either directly constrains
policy decisions (for example, by giving the legislature a veto of interest-rate changes) or
eliminates key bulwarks of CBI (for example, by allowing governors to be dismissed for political
reasons).
15
The most dramatic reform of the Fed, in 1935, generally increased the independence
and effectiveness of its monetary function; the Dodd-Frank reforms of 2010 focused on lending
and regulatory authorities and did not materially change the Fed’s monetary role. Likewise, it is
not inconsistent with CBI that the reappointment of a policymaker depends on his or her success
at meeting mandated goals, so long as the promise of reappointment is not used to influence or
politicize particular policy decisions. This latter distinction is admittedly not always sharp, but it
is supported by the tradition of appointing central bank governors based on professional
qualifications rather than political experience and by cultures of professionalism and
nonpartisanship at central banks, including the Fed of course.
This description of CBI captures, in general terms, the current institutional and political
equilibrium in most advanced economies, and it remains an influential principle constraining the
relationship between politicians and central bank governors in many countries. Several
questions arise: (1) What is the rationale for CBI in the current environment? (2) Should CBI
apply equally to all central bank activities? (3) Will CBI continue to be a key principle of
monetary policymaking in the future?
15
Binder and Spindel (2017) provide evidence for a political cycle in which Congress largely ignores the Fed during
good times but acts to reform the institution after episodes of poor economic or financial performance.
32
On the first question, the most prominent argument of the research literature is that CBI
helps to solve time consistency problems of monetary policy (Kydland and Prescott, 1977; Barro
and Gordon, 1980). The basic story, with some simplification, posits that promises of low
inflation may be difficult to make credible if decisionmakers are too focused on the short term.
In particular, if the public expects low inflation, then policymakers may be tempted to achieve a
short-run increase in output by engineering a near-term inflation “surprise.” But the public will
come to expect such surprises, with the result in equilibrium being that inflation and inflation
expectations are higher than desired, with no ultimate benefit in terms of higher output. CBI
addresses the inflation credibility problem, in this traditional view, because independent central
bankersperhaps because they are selected for their hawkish tendencies, or because of
professional or institutional incentiveswill be seen by the public as less inclined than
politicians to push for short-term output gains at the expense of higher inflation. The canonical
example of “credibility through delegation” is Jimmy Carter’s appointment of Paul Volcker to
the Fed (Rogoff, 1985), and, indeed, it’s very plausible that central bank independence has
contributed to the global reduction in inflation of the past couple of decades. Essentially, in this
view, an independent central bank is a commitment device by which politicians control their own
inflationary biases.
The general thesis that independent central bankers have longer horizons, and are thus
better able than short-term-oriented politicians to take into account the longer-term interests of
the economy, rings true, as I’ll discuss. However, the specific argument that CBI reduces
inflation bias is looking shaky these days. In recent years, the problem faced by central banks
has been too little, rather than too much, inflation. Moreover, some of the strongest political
opposition to the strong monetary measures of the Fed and other major central banks have come
not from those who wanted the monetary authorities to do more, but from those who wanted
them to do less. I have already mentioned the 2010 letter from Congressional leaders to the
Federal Open Market Committee warning against embarking on a new round of quantitative
easing. Similar objections to monetary easing have been raised in Europeespecially in
Germany, where quantitative easing and low interest rates have provoked popular protest and
court casesand elsewhere. The phenomenon of intense political opposition to easy money has
diverse causes, including the political power of creditors (savers and financial institutions), but in
any case it is difficult to reconcile with the traditional time consistency story.
33
One might be tempted to conclude that, in a low-inflation world, CBI is no longer
desirable, and that central banks should coordinate directly with governments when needed to get
higher inflation (Eggertsson, 2013). I’ll return to the issue of central bank-government
coordination below. But the point I want to make here is that the time consistency argument for
CBI was never the complete rationale, and that there are other good reasons to delegate monetary
policy to an independent central bank:
First, monetary policymaking can be highly technical. Congress hires the Fed to manage
monetary policy in part for the same reasons that I hire a professional to solve my plumbing
problems—and while I hold the plumber accountable for fixing the problem, I don’t second-
guess the specific actions that he takes, because I recognize that my kibitzing would only worsen
the outcomes.
Second, monetary policy is also often time-sensitive. It needs to be managed by a body
that can respond quickly and accurately to changing economic and financial conditions.
Third, effective monetary policy requires consistent, coherent, and timely communication
with financial markets. Legislatures are not equipped to do this, and even ex post interference
with central bank decisions or communication will create uncertainty in markets and reduce the
effectiveness of monetary policy.
If monetary policy’s technical aspects, need for timeliness, and market sensitivity were
the only reasons for delegating this responsibility, then it might be sufficient to have monetary
policy run out of the finance ministry or Treasury, rather than by an independent central bank.
Indeed, there have been significant examples of monetary policy oversight by developed-
economy finance ministries, as recently as the 1990s in the United Kingdom and Japan for
example. An argument for delegating monetary policy to the Treasury is precisely that it might
be more democratically responsive, at least in the short run. Moreover, as noted earlier,
monetary policy (including quantitative easing) can have fiscal implications, including for
seigniorage revenue, debt management, and the functioning of government debt markets,
providing some additional rationale for leaving monetary policy to finance ministers.
However, these points notwithstanding, the longstanding global trend toward entrusting
monetary policy to independent central banks rather than finance ministries seems justified by
the weight of experience. First, monetary policy operates with substantial lags, and campaigns
of policy easing and tightening can play out over a number of years. So, even if inflation bias is
34
itself not a problem, it is important that monetary policymakers keep a longer-term perspective
and ensure policy continuity and coherence over time. Finance ministers (who in most
jurisdictions are elected politicians) may turn over quicklyas Fed chair I worked with four
Treasury secretaries (two Republicans and two Democrats), and Alan Greenspan worked with
sevenand changes in government shorten time horizons as well. For similar reasons,
independent central banks are better placed to develop long-run institutional credibilityto
anchor inflation expectations, establish a reputation for carrying through on forward guidance, to
establish a predictable reaction function, and to avoid policy lurches. Second, even beyond their
effects on time horizons, political considerations would create other problems for a Treasury-led
monetary policy. For example, there would be suspicions of (and temptations toward) “spin”
around economic forecasts and the timing of key policy actions or announcements. Would a
finance ministry be tempted to cut interest rates to distract from an unrelated political setback?
Even if not, would the markets suspect that that might happen? Fiscal considerations, mentioned
above as an argument for keeping monetary policy in the Treasury, might cut the other way in a
short-run political context: Would there be concerns, for example, that the Treasury is setting
interest rates to influence the size of the government’s current deficit?
In sum, the avoidance of inflation bias is far from the only rationale for delegating
monetary policy to an independent central bank. Other reasons include the technical, time-
sensitive, and market-sensitive aspects of monetary policy-making; the benefits of the longer-
term perspective on the economy that apolitical central bankers bring; the development over time
of institutional credibility and predictability; and the avoidance of incentives to react to short-
term political developments. The delegation of monetary policy to central banks may also be in
the interest of politicians, as well as in the public interest, which helps explain why it’s
sustainable. For example, delegation provides distance, allowing politicians to enjoy the benefits
of a good economy while having someone else to blame if things go wrong (Binder and Spindel,
2017). Less cynically, politicians may recognize that delegation, by putting policy in the hands
of specialists and eliminating their own incentives to over-react to short-term political pressures,
is good for the economy and their constituents as well as for themselves (Eggertsson and Le
Borgne, 2007).
35
These arguments for CBI pertain primarily to monetary policy. What about other central
bank activities? Should they be carried out with the same presumption of independence as
monetary policy?
CBI is an instrumental principle, not an ideological or philosophical proposition: It
makes sense when it leads to better policy outcomes (on average) and not otherwise. Thus, the
applicability of CBI may vary according to policy function or to economic circumstances. In its
supervisory functions, for example, the central bank should not make special claims to
independence, over and above that afforded to other regulators. Independence seems well
justified in some aspects of supervision; for example, allowing political interference in the
determination of (say) the capital adequacy of a particular bank would involve obvious risks and
potential conflicts of interest. But legislators may appropriately weigh in on regulatory and
supervisory policies applied to the banking system broadly. In the response to a systemic crisis,
the case for CBI is that it may allow the central bank to fulfill its vital lender-of-last-resort
function rapidly and effectively, making use of supervisory and other confidential information.
However, in a financial crisis, coordination of the central bank with the executive (including
other agencies) and the legislature may be essential for achieving stability. In the 2007-09 crisis,
the Fed and other central banks worked closely with finance ministers, without compromising
their independence in monetary policy or as lenders of last resort.
A special case of interest arises when an economy faces significant deflation risk, and
when monetary policy is unable to contain the problem on its own. As Eggertsson (2013) has
pointed out, that situation turns the traditional “inflation bias” argument for independence on its
head: If the purpose of CBI is to avoid inflation bias in normal times, then it would seem to
follow that CBI should deliberately be sacrificed when more rather than less inflation is desired.
Historically, of course, inflation has often been associated with the subjugation of the central
bank to the fiscal authorities.
The perspective of the present paper offers a somewhat different take on this issue. CBI
does not depend only on the inflation bias argument, I have argued; there are other reasons to
delegate monetary policy to an independent, technocratic institution. Accordingly, the absence
of inflation is not in itself a reason to abandon CBI. However, in my view, CBI does not
necessarily preclude coordination of monetary policymakers with the fiscal authorities, if two
conditions are satisfied:
36
First, the goals of the coordination should be both consistent with the central bank’s
mandate and not achievable in the absence of coordination. So, if fiscal-monetary coordination
is essential for meeting the central bank’s inflation goal or to preserve financial stability, then it’s
better to coordinate than to fail to meet the mandated objectives. In contrast, the central bank
should not coordinate if the result is inconsistent with or outside of its mandates, or if its
mandated objectives can be achieved without coordination. In particular, explicit fiscal-
monetary coordination to raise inflation should not be considered except as a last resort, when
the central bank has determined that it cannot independently achieve its inflation target.
Second, the central bank must continuously evaluate whether the first condition is
satisfied, retaining the power to stop coordinating at any point if it is not. These two criteria
seem to me to protect CBI, which has long-run value for the economy, while not ruling out
temporary periods of monetary-fiscal coordination that may be essential for achieving key policy
goals.
As a positive matter, will CBI survive? There are certainly worrying signs. In the United
States, the Fed remains unpopular in many quarters, and hostility between some members of
Congress and Fed leadership has been frequently evident. The Fed also has fewer institutional
protections than most other advanced-economy central banks; in particular, as noted, its policy
independence is not explicitly protected by law or treaty (except indirectly, through the speed
bumps mentioned earlier).
However, there are also reasons to be guardedly optimistic: First, recent economic
performanceat least the dimensions of it amenable to monetary policyhas been good, with
the Fed near its inflation and unemployment objectives. At the same time, post-crisis reforms
have addressed many aspects of the crisis response, including the most unpopular interventions.
The objective case for major institutional change at this point thus seems rather weak. Second,
as is normal in a democracy, the winners of recent elections are in the process of appointing new
leadership at the central bank, with the result that the Fed’s current political opponents will now
find themselves with a stake in the institution’s success. Since CBI is important for that success,
the new political leadership may increasingly appreciate see the value of preserving that norm.
Continued vigilance is essential, of course. The greatest danger is short memories. The
financial crisis and the ensuing recession were fought with financial and monetary policies that,
while ultimately successful, engendered political backlash. After the crisis, necessary reforms
37
helped to strengthen the system and to rationalize crisis-fighting authorities. The risk is that
politicians may be tempted to constrain or eliminate some of the powers, including monetary
powers, that proved essential in the past decade. Such changes might have little immediate
effect, but unless carefully thought through they could expose the American and world
economies to severe financial and economic risks in the future.
CONCLUSIONS
Even as central banks emerge from the shadow of the global financial crisis and the
ensuing recession, they face new challenges. Among the most important of these are the
constraints on conventional monetary policy posed by low inflation and low nominal interest
rates. In this note, I have argued that unconventional tools, especially forward guidance and
quantitative easing, can provide significant additional scope for monetary policy.
However, even with additional tools, and absent reliable fiscal support, existing monetary
frameworks may prove insufficient to offset a severe economic slowdown. That leads to the
question of whether alternative monetary frameworks could increase the potency of monetary
policy. One leading suggestion, to keep the current inflation-targeting regime but to raise the
inflation target to 3 or 4 percent, raises a number of concerns. Targeting the price level is a
better approach, but it also has drawbacks, including the communications challenge of making
such a large change in the policy framework and the requirement that central banks reverse
(rather than “look through”) temporary inflation shocks. In this paper I have proposed for
consideration a “temporary price-level targeting” approach, which applies only at times at which
policy rates are at or very close to zero; at other times, standard inflation targeting would prevail.
Under this approach, monetary policymakers would commit in advance not to raise rates from
zero at least until 1) average inflation over the entire ZLB period is at target and 2)
unemployment has returned to normal ranges. This approach involves only modest changes to
the current framework, and it is consistent with the Fed’s current mandates for maximum
employment and price stability.
The low-inflation, low-rate environment also raises questions about central bank
independence, which the economics literature has rationalized as a bulwark against high
inflation. I agree with Eggertsson (2013) that fiscal-monetary coordination, rather than
independent monetary policy, may at times be necessary to fight persistent deflation or low
38
inflation. However, I argue that the case for CBI goes well beyond the avoidance of inflation
bias and is based on factors that include technical competence, institutional credibility, and the
need for a longer-term perspective. I am hopeful that CBI will survive in the United States and
other advanced economies, but memories are short and thus vigilance in defense of CBI will be
important.
APPENDIX: THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN THE TEMPORARY PRICE LEVEL
TARGET AND THE KILEY-ROBERTS SHADOW RATE POLICY
As noted in the text, Kiley and Roberts (2017) postulate a so-called shadow rate policy
rule, which they show by simulations to reduce (indeed, largely eliminate) the effects of the ZLB
on macro outcomes. A potential disadvantage of their approach, however, is that it relies on
unobservables and may be difficult to explain. In this appendix, I show that my temporary price
level target is closely related to the Kiley-Roberts (KR) policy as applied to ZLB periods.
However, unlike KR, who assume that the shadow rate rule applies at all times, my approach
assumes that a conventional policy rule is used away from the ZLB.
To be concrete, suppose that the ordinary policy rule followed by the central bank (away
from the ZLB) is a Taylor rule with a lagged interest rate term:
(1)
 
 
 
 
 

The notation is as usual (i is the policy rate, π is inflation, y is the output gap; r, a, b, and c are
parameters; the subscript t is time, measured say in quarters). This rule is incomplete, however in
that it does not specify how the rate is set when the notional rate implied by equation (1) is
negative. The usual solution is to assume that the actual rate is the maximum of the rate implied
by equation (1) and zero. However, as KR show, when the neutral nominal interest rate is low,
the use of policy rules like equation (1), modified only by the non-negativity constraint, can lead
to frequent encounters with the ZLB and poor economic performance.
16
16
Note, though, that Kiley and Roberts looks specifically at the case in which there is no lagged interest rate term,
. I include the lagged term both for realism and because lagged responses tend to improve policy performance
when the ZLB is relevant. Empirical evaluations of this approach should therefore allow for the lagged term.
39
An alternative means of dealing with the ZLB constraint, explored by KR, begins by
specifying a shadow policy rate, which is non-zero (negative) only when the actual policy rate is
constrained by the ZLB. Following KR, I define the shadow rate by:
(2)
 
 
 

where d and e are parameters. As in KR, the evolution of the shadow rate is specified in first
differences. The shadow rate is not directly observable but is instead a device for determining
when the central bank lifts the actual policy rate, i, from zero. In analogy to KR, I assume the
actual and shadow policy rates interact as follows.
17
Suppose the economy starts out in a
“normal” (non-ZLB) regime, with the actual policy rate above zero and given by the Taylor rule,
equation (1). In this normal regime, with , set
. The economy evolves over time
until, at some point, the Taylor rule implies a negative policy rate. In that period, there is a
regime switch: Now and
is determined by equation (2), with the lagged value of
initially equal to zero. Presumably, in this regime
is negative because inflation and output are
low.
Now assume that the economy remains in the ZLB regime (with the actual interest rate
 until the shadow rate returns to (crosses) zero from below, at which point the Taylor rule
takes over again (i is determined by equation (1) if it is non-negative, and is equal to zero
otherwise) and the shadow rate is once again set to zero. In short, the basic idea is that the
Taylor rule applies when the policy rate is away from zero, while the shadow rate determines the
time of exit from the ZLB. Importantly, in its first-difference form, the shadow rate reflects the
cumulative departures of inflation and output from target during the ZLB period, i.e., it is
history-dependent in Woodford’s sense. Accordingly, as the KR simulations confirm, the
introduction of the shadow rate delays the exit from an adverse ZLB episode, improving
performance significantly relative to purely forward-looking policy rules.
The shadow rate formulation is appealing, but in practice, it could prove challenging to
try to communicate policy to the public in terms of a shadow rate. As noted, the shadow rate is
17
Kiley-Roberts assume that a policy rule of the form of (2) applies at all times. I differ from their treatment by
letting the shadow rate rule apply during ZLB episodes and setting policy by the inertial Taylor rule, equation (1), at
other times.
40
not directly observable by the public, and its value depends on specific choices of the form and
parameter values of the equation determining
, equation (2). If possible, it seems preferable to
express the central bank’s necessary condition for exiting from the ZLB in terms of macro
observables, rather than in terms of the shadow rate. I show now how to do that.
Suppose the economy enters a ZLB episode in period 0. In what period, call it period k,
will the economy exit from the ZLB? Recursively solving equation (2), the exit period k is
determined endogenously by the condition that the shadow rate in period k crosses zero:
(3)
 
 


Suppose for the moment that the weight on the output gap in the shadow rate equation is zero
( . Then equation (3) is satisfied when average inflation over the ZLB period is at 2
percent, or, alternatively, when the cumulative inflation shortfalls from target are made up. So,
under the admittedly restrictive assumption that , the shadow rate policy is equivalent to a
temporary price level target, applied only during ZLB episodes.
If , then the criterion for exit from the ZLB, equation (3), is a weighted average of
the inflation shortfall and the cumulative output gap, with an explicit relative weight. I’m not
sure that a weighted-average criterion for exiting the ZLB would be workable in practice,
although it should not be ruled out. A simpler alternative in the spirit of equation (3) is to add a
condition on the unemployment rate to the exit criterion, as discussed in the main text. So, for
example, if both inflation and output drop below target/potential during the ZLB period, then a
necessary condition for exit in period k would be
, or, equivalently,

. In
practice, then, the central bank could stipulate in advance two necessary conditions for exit from
the ZLB: that (1) average inflation over the entire ZLB period is (at least) back to target and (2)
the current unemployment rate is no higher than the central bank’s (publicly announced) estimate
of NAIRU. This conditionality is similar to the FOMC’s (Odyssean) forward guidance a few
years ago when it tied rate increases to the inflation goal and to the level of the unemployment
rate (FOMC, 2012).
The shadow-rate specification ties the exit date from the ZLB to the temporary price level
target. After the exit, in this approach, the policy rate is determined by the standard Taylor rule.
41
An alternative would be to add the cumulative inflation shortfall since the beginning of the ZLB
period directly to the Taylor rule:
(4)
 
 
 
 
 

   

where t1 is the period in which the economy last entered the ZLB regime (so the last term is the
average inflation shortfall since then) and f is a parameter. This formulation does not require a
shadow rate computation; instead, the policy rate is the max of the value of equation (4) and
zero. The inflation shortfall term is to be understood to be present in equation (4) only during and
immediately after a ZLB episode, and to drop out at other times. Qualitatively, the thrust of (4)
is that central bankers would take the cumulative inflation shortfall as an additional consideration
for policy during and immediately after a ZLB episode.
42
REFERENCES
Atkins, Ralph, “Germany Attacks US Economic Policy,” Financial Times, November 7, 2010,
http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/c0dca084-ea6c-11df-b28d-00144feab49a.html#axzz3c6g2tFNf.
Auerbach, Alan J. and Yuriy Gorodnichenko, “Fiscal Stimulus and Fiscal Sustainability,”
Jackson Hole Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, WY, August 29
th
, 2017.
Barro, Robert J. and David B. Gordon, “Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of
Monetary Policy,” NBER Working Paper 1079, Cambridge, MA, February 1983.
Bank of Japan, “Announcements of the Monetary Policy Meeting Decision (Feb. 12),” Tokyo,
February 12
th
, 1999, https://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/release_1999/k990212c.htm/.
Bauer, Michael D and Glenn D. Rudebusch, “The Signaling Channel for Federal Reserve Bond
Purchases,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2011-21, San Francisco, CA,
April 2013.
Baker, Dean, Laurence Ball, Jared Bernstein, Heather Boushey, Josh Bivens, David
Blanchflower, J. Bradford DeLong, …, Justin Wolfers to Chair Yellen and the Board of
Governors, The Center for Popular Democracy, June 8
th
, 2017,
http://populardemocracy.org/sites/default/files/Rethink%202%25%20letter.pdf.
Bernanke, Ben S., “Deflation: Making Sure ‘It’ Doesn’t Happen Here,” Remarks at the National
Economists Club, Washington DC, November 21
st
, 2002.
Bernanke, Ben S., “The Global Savings Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit,” Remarks at
the Sandridge Lecture, Virginia Association of Economists, Richmond, VA, March 10
th
, 2005.
Bernanke, Ben S., “The Crisis and the Policy Response,” The Stamp Lecture, London School of
Economics, London, England, January 13
th
, 2009.
Bernanke, Ben S., “Monetary Policy since the Onset of the Crisis,” Remarks at the Jackson Hole
Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, WY, August 31
st
, 2012.
Bernanke, Ben S., “Monetary policy and inequality,” Brookings Institution blog, Washington
DC, June 1
st
, 2015.
Bernanke, Ben S., “What tools does the Fed have left? Part 1: Negative interest rates,” Brookings
Institution blog, Washington DC, March 18
th
, 2016a.
Bernanke, Ben S., “What tools does the Fed have left? Part 2: Targeting longer-term interest
rates,” Brookings Institution blog, Washington DC, March 24
th
, 2016b.
43
Bernanke, Ben S., “Modifying the Fed’s policy framework: Does a higher inflation target beat
negative interest rates?,” Brookings Institution blog, Washington DC, September 13
th
, 2016c.
Bernanke, Ben S., “The latest from the Bank of Japan,” Brookings Institution blog, Washington
DC, September 21
st
, 2016d.
Bhattarai, Saroj and Christopher Neely, “A Survey of the Empirical Literature on U.S.
Unconventional Monetary Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of Saint Louis Working Paper 2016-
021A, St. Louis, MO, October 28
th
, 2016, https://dx.doi.org/10.20955/wp.2016.021.
Binder, Sarah and Mark Spindel, “The Myth of Independence: How Congress Governs the
Federal Reserve,” Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, September 2017.
Bivens, Josh, “Gauging the Impact of the Fed on Inequality During the Great Recession,”
Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy at the Brookings Institution, Hutchins Center
Working Paper #12, Washington DC, June 1
st
, 2015.
Bonis, Brian, Jane Ihrig, and Min Wei, "The Effect of the Federal Reserve's Securities Holdings
on Longer-term Interest Rates," Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, FEDS
Notes, Washington DC, April 20, 2017, https://doi.org/10.17016/2380-7172.1977.
Bowman, David, Christopher Erceg, and Mike Leahy, “Strategies for Targeting Interest Rates
Out the Yield Curve,” Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) Memorandum, Washington,
DC, October 13
th
, 2010. Released by the FOMC secretariat on January 29
th
, 2016.
Burke, Chris, Spence Hilton, Ruth Judson, Kurt Lewis, and David Skeie, “Reducing the IOER
Rate: An Analysis of Options,” Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) Memorandum,
Washington, DC, August 5
th
, 2010. Released by the FOMC secretariat on January 29
th
, 2016.
Byrne, David and Dan Sichel, “The productivity slowdown is even more puzzling than you
think,” The Center for Economic Policy Research, Vox Policy Portal, August 22, 2017,
http://voxeu.org/article/productivity-slowdown-even-more-puzzling-you-think.
Caballero, Ricardo J., Emmanuel Farhi, and Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, “The Safe Assets
Shortage Conundrum,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 31, No. 3, Summer 2017, 29-46.
Campbell, Jeffrey R., Charles L. Evans, Jonas D. M. Fisher, and Alejandro Justiniano,
“Macroeconomic Effects of Federal Reserve Forward Guidance,” Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, Washington DC, Spring 2012, 1-80.
Chaurushiya, Radha and Ken Kuttner, “Targeting the Yield Curve: The Experience of the
Federal Reserve, 1942-51,” Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) Memorandum,
Washington, DC, June 18
th
, 2003. Released by the FOMC Secretariat on January 29
th
, 2016.
Chen, Catherine, Macro Cipriani, Gabriele La Spada, Philip Mulder, and Neha Shah, “Money
Market Funds and the New SEC Regulation,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Liberty Street
44
Economics (blog), March 20
th
, 2017,
http://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2017/03/money-market-funds-and-the-new-sec-
regulation.html.
Chinn, Menzie D., “The Once and Future Global Imbalances? Interpreting the Post-Crisis
Record,” Jackson Hole Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, WY, August 26
th
, 2017.
Danmarks Nationalbank, “Interest Rate Reduction,” Press release, February 5
th
, 2015,
http://www.nationalbanken.dk/en/pressroom/Pages/2015/02/DNN201521789.aspx.
Del Negro, Marco, Marc P. Giannoni, Domenico Giannone, and Andrea Tambalotti, “Safety,
Liquidity, and the Natural Rate of Interest,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
Washington DC, Spring 2017, 235-294.
Dell'Ariccia, Giovanni, Vikram Haksar, and Tommaso Mancini-Griffoli, “Negative Interest Rate
Policies-Initial Experiences and Assessments,” International Monetary Fund, IMF Policy Paper,
Washington, DC, August 3
rd
, 2017.
Diercks, Anthony M, “The Reader’s Guide to Optimal Monetary Policy,” Social Science
Research Network, June 18
th
, 2017, https://ssrn.com/abstract=2989237.
Eggertsson, Gauti and Eric Le Borgne, “Dynamic Incentives and the Optimal Delegation of
Political Power,” International Monetary Fund, IMF Working Paper, April 2007.
Eggertsson, Gauti and Michael Woodford, “The Zero Bound on Interest Rates and Optimal
Monetary Policy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Washington DC, Spring 2003, 139-
233.
Eggertsson, Gauti, “Fiscal Multipliers and Policy Coordination,” in Luis Felipe Cespedes and
Jordi Gali (eds.), Fiscal Policy and Macroeconomic Performance, Central Bank of Chile,
Chapter 6, 175-234, 2013, http://si2.bcentral.cl/public/pdf/banca-
central/pdf/v17/Vol17_175_234.pdf.
Erceg, Christopher, Michael Kiley, and David López-Salido, “Alternative Monetary Policy
Frameworks,” Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) Memorandum, Washington, DC,
October 6
th
, 2011. Released by the FOMC Secretariat on February 15
th
, 2017.
Engen, Eric M., Thomas Laubach, and David Reifschneider, “The Macroeconomic Effects of the
Federal Reserve’s Unconventional Monetary Policies,” Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2015-005, Washington DC, January
14
th
, 2015.
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), “Press Release,” Washington DC, August 12
th
, 2003,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/press/monetary/2003/20030812/default.htm.
45
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), “FOMC statement,” Washington DC, December 16
th
,
2008, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20081216b.htm.
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), “FOMC statement,” Washington DC, March 18
th
,
2009, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20090318a.htm.
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), “FOMC statement,” Washington DC, November 4
th
,
2009, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20091104a.htm.
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), “FOMC statement,” Washington DC, August 9
th
,
2011, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20110809a.htm.
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), “Federal Reserve issues FOMC statement,”
Washington DC, January 25
th
, 2012,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20120125a.htm.
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), “Federal Reserve issues FOMC statement,”
Washington DC, September 13
th
, 2012,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20120913a.htm
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), “Federal Reserve issues FOMC statement,”
Washington DC, December 12
th
, 2012,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20121212a.htm.
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), “FOMC issues addendum to the Policy
Normalization Principles and Plans, Washington DC, June 14
th
, 2017,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20170614c.htm.
Federal Reserve Board of Governors, “Federal Reserve Board announces Reserve Bank income
and expense data and transfers to the Treasury for 2016,” Press Release, January 10
th
, 2017,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/other20170110a.htm.
Femia, Katherine, Steven Friedman, and Brian Sack, “The Effects of Policy Guidance on
Perceptions of the Fed’s Reaction Function,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report
No. 652, New York, New York, November 2013.
Feroli, Michael, David Greenlaw, Peter Hooper, Frederic S. Mishkin, and Amir Sufi, “Language
After Liftoff: Fed Communication Away from the Zero Lower Bound,” University of Chicago
Booth School of Business, 2016 US Monetary Policy Forum, New York, New York, February
26
th
, 2016.
Fleming, Sam, “Fed faces its critics at Jackson Hole,” Financial Times, Jackson Hole, WY,
August 27
th
, 2016, https://www.ft.com/content/193b2db8-6b27-11e6-a0b1-d87a9fea034f.
Gagnon, Etienne, Benjamin K. Johannsen, and David Lopez-Salido, “Understanding the New
Normal: The Role of Demographics,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
46
Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2016-080, Washington DC, October 2016a,
http://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2016.080
Gagnon, Joseph E., “Quantitative Easing: An Underappreciated Success,” Peterson Institute for
International Economics, Policy Brief Number PB16-4, Washington DC, April 2016b.
Garnham, Peter and Jonathan Wheatley, “Brazil in ‘currency war’ alert,” Financial Times,
September 28
th
, 2010, https://www.ft.com/content/33ff9624-ca48-11df-a860-00144feab49a.
Gaspar, Vítor, Frank Smets, and David Vestin, “Is Time Ripe for Price Level Path Stability?,”
European Central Bank Working Paper Series No. 818, October 2007.
Greenwood, Robin, Samuel G. Hanson, Joshua S. Rudolph, and Lawrence H. Summers,
“Government Debt Management at the Zero Lower Bound,” Hutchins Center on Fiscal and
Monetary Policy at the Brookings Institution, Hutchins Center Working Paper #5, Washington
DC, September 30
th
, 2014.
Guthrie, Graeme and Julian Wright, “Open Mouth Operations,” Journal of Monetary Economics,
vol. 46, issue 2, October 2000, 489-516,
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304393200000350.
Herszenhorn, David M., “Dear Mr. Bernanke: No Pressure, but…,” The New York Times, The
Caucus (blog), November 17
th
, 2010, https://thecaucus.blogs.nytimes.com/2010/11/17/dear-mr-
bernanke-no-pressure-but/?mcubz=0.
Huther, Jeffrey, Jane Ihrig, and Elizabeth Klee, “The Federal Reserve’s Portfolio and its Effect
on Interest Rates,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Finance and Economics
Discussion Series 2017-075, Washington DC, June 2017,
https://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2017.075.
Kiley, Michael T. and John M. Roberts, “Monetary Policy in a Low Interest Rate World,”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Washington DC, Spring 2017, 317-396.
Krugman, Paul, “It’s Baaack: Japan’s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap,” Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, Washington DC, Fall 1998, 137-205.
Kydland, Finn E. and Edward C. Prescott, “Rules rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of
Optimal Plans,” Journal of Political Economy, Volume 85, Issue 3, June 1977, 473-492.
Leubsdorf, Ben, “Activists in Jackson Hole Pressure Fed on Inflation, Endorse Yellen,” Wall
Street Journal, August 24
th
, 2017, https://www.wsj.com/articles/activists-in-jackson-hole-
pressure-fed-on-inflation-endorse-yellen-1503621341.
Matthews, Dylan, “Did the stimulus work? A review of the nine best studies on the subject,”
Washington Post, August 24
th
, 2011, https://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/ezra-klein/post/did-
47
the-stimulus-work-a-review-of-the-nine-best-studies-on-the-
subject/2011/08/16/gIQAThbibJ_blog.html?utm_term=.5a6527454988.
Mui, Ylan Q., “Why this top official thinks the Federal Reserve should raise interest rates this
year,” Washington Post, Wonkblog, August 11
th
, 2016,
https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2016/08/11/why-this-top-official-thinks-the-
federal-reserve-should-raise-interest-rates-this-year/?utm_term=.33fb6184fc76.
Rachel, Lukasz and Thomas D. Smith, “Secular drivers of the global real interest rate,” Bank of
England Staff Working Paper No. 571, December 2015.
Reifschneider, David and John C. Williams, “Three Lessons for Monetary Policy in a Low-
Inflation Era,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 2000, vol. 32, issue 4, 936-66.
Rogoff, Kenneth S., “The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, November 1985, 1169-1189.
Rogoff, Kenneth S., “The Curse of Cash,” Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, September
6
th
, 2016.
Summers, Lawrence H., Have We Entered an Age of Secular Stagnation? IMF Fourteenth
Annual Research Conference in Honor of Stanley Fischer, IMF Economic Review, Vol. 63,
Issue 1, Washington DC, May 2015, 277-280, http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2015.6.
Svensson, Lars E. O., “Price-Level Targeting versus Inflation Targeting: A Free Lunch?,”
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, August 1999, vol. 31, no. 3, part 1, 277-295.
Swanson, Eric T., “Measuring the Effects of Federal Reserve Forward Guidance and Asset
Purchases on Financial Markets,” NBER Working Paper 23311, Cambridge, MA, June 2017.
Taylor, John B., “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy, 39, North-Holland, 195-214, 1993.
Taylor, John B. and Paul D. Ryan, “Refocus the Fed on Price Stability Instead of Bailing Out
Fiscal Policy,” Investor’s Business Daily Op-ed, December 1
st
, 2010,
http://media.hoover.org/sites/default/files/documents/Refocus-Fed-on-Price-Stability-Instead-of-
Bailing-Out-Fiscal-Policy.pdf.
Tobin, James, “How Dead is Keynes?,” Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale
University, Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 458, June 1977.
United States. Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, “Federal Reserve’s
First Monetary Policy Report to Congress for 2016February 11
th
, 114th Cong. 1st sess.
Washington: Federal Reserve Board, 2016 (statement of Janet L. Yellen, Chair, Federal Board).
48
United States. Cong. House Committee on Financial Services and Senate Committee on
Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, “Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to CongressJuly
12
th
and 13
th
, 115th Cong. 1st sess. Washington: Federal Reserve Board, 2017 (statement
of Janet L. Yellen, Chair, Federal Board).
US Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), “SEC Adopts Money Market Fund Reform
Rules,” Washington DC, July 23
rd
, 2014, https://www.sec.gov/news/press-release/2014-143.
Wall Street Journal, “Open Letter to Ben Bernanke,” Real Time Economics (blog), November
15
th
2010, https://blogs.wsj.com/economics/2010/11/15/open-letter-to-ben-bernanke/.
Wall Street Journal, “Full Text: Republicans’ Letter to Bernanke Questioning More Fed Action,”
Real Time Economics (blog), September 20
th
, 2011,
https://blogs.wsj.com/economics/2011/09/20/full-text-republicans-letter-to-bernanke-
questioning-more-fed-action/.
Werning, Ivan, “Managing a Liquidity Trap: Monetary and Fiscal Policy”, NBER Working
Paper No. 17344, Cambridge, MA, August 2011.
Williams, John C., “Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: Putting Theory into Practice,”
Hutchins Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy at the Brookings Institution, Hutchins Center
Working Paper #3, Washington DC, January 16
th
, 2014.
Williams, John C., “Discussion of Language after Liftoff: Fed Communication Away from the
Zero Lower Bound,” Presentation at the US. Monetary Policy Forum, New York, New York,
February 26
th
, 2016.
Williams, John C., “Preparing for the Next Storm: Reassessing Frameworks & Strategies in a
Low R-Star World,” Remarks at the Shadow Open Market Committee, New York, New York,
May 5
th
, 2017.
Woodford, Michael, “Comment on ‘Heeding Daedalus: Optimal Inflation and the Zero Lower
Bound’,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Washington DC, Spring, 2009, 3845.
Yellen, Janet L., “Opening Remarks: The Federal Reserve’s Monetary Policy Toolkit: Past,
Present and Future,” Remarks at the Jackson Hole Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, WY,
August 26
th
, 2016.