Toward Fair and Sustainable Capitalism
A Comprehensive Proposal to Help American Workers, Restore Fair
Gainsharing Between Employees and Shareholders, and Increase
American Competitiveness by Reorienting Our Corporate Governance
System Toward Sustainable Long-Term Growth and Encouraging
Investments in America’s Future
By
Leo E. Strine, Jr.
*
A New Deal For This New Century:
Making Our Economy Work For All
October 3-4, 2019
New York University’s
Constance Milstein and Family Global Academic Center
Washington, D.C.
*
Chief Justice, Delaware Supreme Court; Adjunct Professor of Law, University of Pennsylvania
Law School; Austin Wakeman Scott Lecturer in Law, Harvard Law School; Senior Fellow,
Harvard Program on Corporate Governance; and Henry Crown Fellow, Aspen Institute.
The author is grateful to Kirby Smith and Reilly Steel for their excellent research and thoughts.
This proposal would not have been possible to prepare without their diligence. Thank you also to
Christine Balaguer and Margaret Pfeiffer for their excellent help, and to David Berger, Jill Fisch,
David Katz, Ted Mirvis, Damon Silvers and Antonio Weiss for helpful discussions and comments
that influenced the Proposal. All errors are on my own.
University of Pennsylvania Law School
ILE
INSTITUTE FOR LAW AND ECONOMICS
A Joint Research Center of the Law School, the Wharton School, and the
Department of Economics in the School of Arts and Sciences
at the University of Pennsylvania
RESEARCH PAPER NO. 19-39
Toward Fair and Sustainable Capitalism
A Comprehensive Proposal to Help American
Workers, Restore Fair Gainsharing Between
Employees and Shareholders, and Increase
American Competitiveness by Reorienting Our
Corporate Governance System
Toward Sustainable Long-Term Growth
and Encouraging Investments in
America’s Future
Leo E. Strine, Jr.
GOVERNMENT OF THE STATE OF DELAWARE - SUPREME COURT OF DELAWARE;
HARVARD LAW SCHOOL; UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA LAW SCHOOL
This paper can be downloaded without charge from the
Social
Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3461924
ISSN 1936-5349 (print)
ISSN 1936-5357 (online)
HARVARD
JOHN M. OLIN CENTER FOR LAW, ECONOMICS, AND BUSINESS
TOWARD FAIR AND SUSTAINABLE CAPITALISM
A COMPREHENSIVE PROPOSAL TO HELP AMERICAN WORKERS, RESTORE FAIR GAINSHARING BETWEEN
EMPLOYEES AND SHAREHOLDERS, AND INCREASE AMERICAN COMPETITIVENESS BY REORIENTING OUR
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE SYSTEM TOWARD SUSTAINABLE LONG-TERM GROWTH AND ENCOURAGING
INVESTMENTS IN AMERICA’S FUTURE
Leo E. Strine, Jr.
Discussion Paper No. 1018
09/2019
Harvard Law School
Cambridge, MA 02138
This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
The Harvard John M. Olin Discussion Paper Series:
http://www.law.harvard.edu/programs/olin_center
The Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3461924
This paper is also Discussion Paper 2019-11 of the
Harvard Law School Program on Corporate Governance
Fair and Sustainable Capitalism Proposal
The incentive system for the governance of American corporations has failed in recent
decades to adequately encourage long-term investment, sustainable business practices, and
most importantly, fair gainsharing between shareholders and workers. That should not be
so. This state of affairs exists in no small part because we have made public companies
more and more responsive to the desires of the stock market, as represented by institutional
investors with a demand for immediate returns. This has resulted in declines in gainsharing
of corporate profits with workers, a large increase in stock buybacks, skyrocketing CEO
pay, and growing inequality.
When looking for the causes of growing inequality and a corporate governance system that
does not work for all, the usual subjects of criticism are the CEOs and boards of large
companies, but very little is said about those who wield over 75% of shareholder voting
power: institutional investors. Most stock today is owned not by mom-and-pop investors
who directly hold stock in individual companies, but by institutional investors who control
human investors’ capital. The majority of middle-class Americans fortunate enough to be
invested in the stock market are in a real way forced capitalists. These worker-investors
must save for retirement through 401(k) and other tax-advantaged investments that require
workers to turn over a portion of every paycheck to a family of mutual funds chosen by
their employer. The institutional investors, not these worker-investors, get to vote the
public company stock that mutual funds buy with human investors’ capital.
Corporations will not give more thoughtful consideration to their employees and social
responsibilitythat is, our corporate governance system and economy will not change
unless the institutional investors who elect corporate boards also support doing so.
Institutional investors have the most influence on corporations, and the imbalance in our
corporate governance system can be fixed only by aligning institutional investors’
incentives with the interests of their end investors: human beings saving for retirement and
their children’s college education. Even more important, human beings who most of all
need American corporations to pay good wages and create good jobs.
The investment horizon of the ultimate source of most companies’ funding—human beings
saving for retirement and educationis long. That long-term horizon is much more
aligned with what it takes to run a real business than the horizon of companies’ direct
shareholders, who are money managers under strong pressure to deliver immediate returns
at all times. As diversified investors whose holdings track the overall economy, human
investors do not benefit when companies offload the costs of their activities, such as carbon
emissions and other pollution, onto others. And as human beings who breathe air, consume
products, and depend on a good job for most of their income, human investors suffer as
citizens when companies take shortcuts that harm the environment, defraud or injure
consumers, or offshore jobs to countries with low wages and few worker protections.
2
Human investors owe most of their wealth to their job. This is true not only for the poorer
half of Americans; it is true of 99% of Americans. On average, Americans get 64% of
their income from wages and another 15% from either retirement payments or other
transfer payments. For the middle and upper-middle class, jobs are even more important,
with wages comprising 70% or more of income. But the importance of work does not stop
there. Those in the 80th to 90th percentiles get 75% of their income from working, and
those in the 95th to 99th percentiles still get over 60% from their labor. As a result, human
investors need companies to do business in a way that provides Americans with access to
good jobs, sustainable wage growth, and a fair share of the wealth that businesses generate.
In short, human investors benefit from sustainable, long-term economic growth and
gainsharing between shareholders and workers, but companies have increasingly failed to
deliver on that promise. For about two and a half decades starting in the late 1940s, workers
and investors shared in the wealth generated by a strong, growing economy. In the early
1970s, accelerating in the 1980s, and continuing since, that social compact has frayed.
Since then, worker productivity has risen by about 70%, but hourly pay has grown by only
12%. Meanwhile, corporate profits have hit record highs. In other words, American
workers are more educated than ever, more skilled, and doing more to create corporate
profits than ever, but they have shared far less in the fruits of that labor.
To help redress this problem, workers must be given more voice within the corporate
boardroom, and top managers and directors must give greater thought to how they treat
their employees. Companies should have board-level committees that ensure quality
wages and fair worker treatment. Labor law reforms should make it easier for employees
to join a union and bargain over wages. Likewise, to hold companies accountable for how
they treat their workers, how they treat their consumers, and whether they operate in an
ethical, sustainable, environmentally responsible manner, the public and investors deserve
better information from companies about their performance on these critical dimensions.
In addressing the decline in fair gainsharing with workers, we also cannot ignore the role
of institutional investors in pushing for immediate returns and the poor incentives that
pressure put on companies to take shortcuts that offload companies’ costs onto others, harm
consumers, and undercut Americans access to quality jobs. In no small part because of
retirement policy decisions by U.S. lawmakers, institutional investors have come to
dominate the governance of large U.S. corporations. In the mid-20th century, individuals
held the vast majority of U.S. public companies’ stock; today, institutional investors own
about 78%. And an increasingly small number of those institutional investors, which
commentators have referred to as the “Big Three” or “Big Four,” are especially dominant.
These institutional investors effectively dictate U.S. corporate policy by voting in corporate
elections and on management and shareholder proposals at annual meetings. Institutional
investors elect companies’ boards of directors. Institutional investors vote on whether to
sell the company, back activist proposals, and support company executives’ compensation
levels. The power they exercise cannot be ignored as a factor in producing the decline in
3
fair gainsharing between workers and corporate shareholders. Ultimately, operating
companies will not act in a more responsible manner unless the institutional investors who
control them support them in doing so.
To ensure that operating companies act more responsibly toward their workers and other
stakeholders, the institutional investors who are responsible for managing most human
investors’ money must vote with their investors’ needs in mind. And for index funds
especially, they should have to tailor their voting policies and recommendations to the fact
that they cannot sell their shares and are invested for the long haul. To be fair, some
institutional investors have started to consider environmental, social, and governance, or
“ESG,” factors. But if we want companies to operate in a socially responsible manner that
creates sustainable profits, then all institutional investors who manage human investors’
money need to factor EESG considerations into their investing and voting decisions, and
emphasize the vital missing “E”—the interests of companies’ employees. That is,
institutional investors must align their voting policies with the interests of their worker-
investors who need not just sustainable corporate profits, but also good jobs, clean air, and
safe products.
If companies are spending too much on stock buybacks, taking environmental shortcuts, or
failing to adequately compensate and invest in their workforce, that is likely because their
stockholdersi.e., institutional investorshave exerted pressures on companies that
encouraged this state of affairs. If the goal is to increase the gainsharing among
corporations and their other stakeholdersworkers, consumers, and societythat can be
achieved only through aligning those doing the votinginstitutional investorswith the
interests of the flesh and blood human beings whose money the institutional investors
manage and control. Creating this alignment is achievable, and can be done through
modest changes to current laws and regulations that govern institutional investors.
Other complementary measures would also help to align incentives and promote
sustainable, long-term economic growth that benefits all. To start, we must consider tax
and accounting policy. That is, we must recognize the role of tax and accounting rules in
creating incentives that encourage speculation and rapid portfolio turnover, rather than
productive, sound long-term investing. As important, our nation has long-term economic
challenges that must be addressed by public investment and incentives that can be
implemented only if we have the funds to pay for them. Most notably, we have a huge
infrastructure and basic research gap that is eroding our competitiveness and diminishing
our quality of life. We also cannot be blind to the reality that we need to supercharge our
efforts to address climate change and to set an example for the world. With real
investments in basic research, cleaner, more efficient infrastructure, and worker training,
we can create jobs in the United States, tackle climate change, help workers in carbon-
intensive industries transition to jobs in emerging clean energy companies, spark
innovation, and enhance the long-term international competitiveness of American
companies. At the same time, by implementing good tax policy that addresses behavior
4
we want to have less of, we can use the savings to finance these investments in the future
that create good jobs that cannot be sent overseas.
Finally, we must address legal changes that have given corporate elites an unfair advantage
over working Americans and human investors, including Supreme Court and regulatory
decisions that have undercut the effectiveness of labor unions, deprived Americans of their
day in court and fueled a massive growth in unchecked corporate political spending.
* * *
The bottom line is that America’s corporations are not playthings. They create jobs,
produce goods and services that consumers depend on, affect the environment we live in,
and build wealth for human investors to save for retirement and their kids’ education. That
is, corporations are societally chartered institutions of enormous importance and value.
Those who govern them ought to be accountable for the generation of durable wealth for
workers, consumers, and human investors. A new accountability system that supports
wealth creation within a system of enlightened capitalismone that aligns the interests of
institutional investors and corporations with those of the human beings whose capital they
controlis needed. With some modest sacrifice by every interest that wields economic
power, we can make our economy work better for all Americans. This Proposal to promote
Fair and Sustainable Capitalism would take several steps to make that goal a reality.
Enhancing Disclosure for Operating Companies on Employee, Environmental,
Social, and Governance Matters to Promote Sustainable, Long-Term Growth and
Gainsharing with Workers
Reforming our corporate governance system starts with the operating companies that make
products and create jobs. If companies do not focus on making sustainable profits by
selling useful products and services, and treat their workforce well, our economy will not
work fairly for everyone. And if institutional investors are going to support and expect
companies to behave in a socially responsible mannerone that serves the interests of
human investors as workers, consumers, and citizens, not just as investors concerned with
short-term changes in the value of their stock portfoliothen they need the right
information to hold companies accountable. As important, EESG disclosure is not just
relevant for investors. It is vital for Americans as human beings who are workers,
consumers of products, and breathers of air. Citizens deserve to have quality information
about how the nation’s most influential businesses are treating their workers and
consumers, and respecting our environment, laws, and ethical standards. The Fair and
Sustainable Capitalism Proposal therefore would:
5
Require large, socially important companies to annually report on their
businessesimpact on workers, consumers, communities, the environment, and
our nation.
o Before institutional investors can hold corporations responsible for providing
long-term growth in a sustainable way that benefits employees, consumers,
and the environment, institutional investors need quality information. The
first step is thus to require companies to disclose more information about
their businesses’ impact on employee, environmental, social, and governance
matters (“EESG,” with an extra “E” for employees). To ensure that more
disclosure requirements do not discourage companies from going public or
encourage them to go private, any reporting requirement should not be based
on whether the firm is publicly traded.
o Under the Proposal, any company with more than $1 billion in annual sales
would be required to annually report information about its business’s impact
on workers, consumers, communities in which the company operates, other
stakeholders, and the environment (including climate change). The
Securities and Exchange Commission would develop rules, in consultation
with the Department of Labor, the Department of Commerce, the Department
of Justice, and the Environmental Protection Agency, to standardize
disclosure so that it is useful to investors, workers, consumers, and other
stakeholders, as well as regulators who protect the public. Reporting
obligations would not be conditioned on whether the company’s stock is
publicly traded, avoiding the perverse effect of encouraging companies to go
private or discouraging emerging companies from going public. These
workable disclosure requirements would help both institutional investors and
the public hold companies accountable for the impact of their businesses on
stakeholders and society as a whole.
Require the boards of large, socially important companies to create workforce
committees to address workforce issues at the board level.
o Union membership has drastically declined from its peak of around 28% of
the workforce in the 1950s to less than 11% today. With this decline, it has
become harder for workers to collectively bargain for fair wages, training
that assures them continued employment, and a safe and hospitable
workplace. Meanwhile, in some other countries, such as Germany, workers
have the right to be represented on the company’s board of directors through
so-called “codetermination, but foreign workers typically do not get the vote
and it is not clear that codetermination fits with our economy. But many
capitalist nations without codetermination require that each company has a
workers’ council or some other mechanism requiring ongoing consultation
6
with workers. The U.S. system stands out for its lack of corporate
governance rules or other policies and practices that ensure companies will
consider worker concerns. Combined with the drop in union representation,
this failure may explain some of the decline in fair gainsharing between
workers and companies that has occurred over the past several decades.
o To make sure that companies give careful consideration to worker concerns
at the board level, the Proposal requires the Securities and Exchange
Commission, the Department of Labor, and the National Labor Relations
Board to jointly develop rules that would require the boards of companies
with more than $1 billion in annual sales to create and maintain a committee
focused on workforce concerns. By requiring these committees at all large
corporations, not just public corporations, more accountability would be
imposed on large private companies, such as those owned by private equity
firms, to treat their workforce fairly. These workforce committees would be
focused on addressing fair gainsharing between workers and investors, the
workers’ interest in training that assures continued employment, and the
workers’ interest in a safe and tolerant workplace. These workforce
committees would also consider whether the company uses substitute forms
of laborsuch as contractorsto fulfill important corporate needs, and
whether those contractors pay their workers fairly, provide safe working
conditions, and are operating in an ethical way, and are not simply being used
to inflate corporate profits at the expense of continuing employment and fair
compensation for direct company employees. Offering a middle-ground
between the current system and “codetermination”-style worker
representation, the committees would be required to develop and disclose a
plan for consulting directly with the company’s workers about important
worker matters such as compensation and benefits, opportunities for
advancement, and training. Finally, the National Labor Relations Act would
be amended to ensure that companies can use dedicated committees to
consult with their workers without running afoul of the Act’s prohibition on
“dominating” labor organizations, provided that the company doesn’t
interfere with, restrain, or coerce employees in the exercise of their rights to
collective bargaining and self-organization. In essence, this would allow for
European-style works councils without impeding union formation and
representation.
Change accounting rules to treat investments in human capital like other long-
term investments and require companies to disclose more information in
narrative form about their human capital investments.
o Accounting rules currently treat human capital investments as a cost that is
expensed immediately instead of a long-term investment that is expensed
7
over time. Given financial markets’ focus on short-term results, this can lead
corporate managers to underinvest in human capital. But investment in
human capital is just as important as other long-term investments in plant and
equipment and should be treated as such when being accounted for on a
firm’s income statement and balance sheet. Providing similar accounting
treatment to human capital investments as other long-term corporate
investments would encourage companies to invest in their workforces and
diminish the incentive for activist hedge funds to campaign to reduce
companies’ spending on their workers just to increase short-term returns.
o To fix this problem, the Proposal would require the Securities and Exchange
Commission to instruct the Financial Accounting Standards Board to revise
generally accepted accounting principles to treat investments in human
capital as capital expenditures like investments in plants, property, and
equipment, and the Commission would develop rules requiring public
companies to disclose in narrative form additional information about their
investments in human capital.
Require companies releasing quarterly earnings guidance to make other
necessary and appropriate disclosures.
o No rational person believes that corporations can deliver consistent, quarter-
to-quarter earnings growth nor that corporations should be managed with that
objective in mind, especially in light of the fact that most of their capital
comes from human investors who are saving for the long run and therefore
need sustainable growth, not bubble returns. Forward-looking quarterly
earnings estimates provide little value to investors but continue to contribute
to managing to the market in an unproductive way. And isolated issuer
restraint is of little utility as competitive realities lead to a collective lack of
discipline and wisdom because CEOs fear the loss of analyst coverage if they
refuse to feed the market beast and their competitors continue to do so.
o The Proposal would have the SEC promulgate rules requiring companies to
disclose more information or adhere to other standards if companies are
going to release forward-looking quarterly earnings estimates. Under the
Proposal, the SEC must require any company that issues quarterly guidance
to maintain, make public, and keep current a long-term plan for earnings
growth and situate any quarterly guidance within the context of that long-
term plan. By requiring companies to disclose long-term plans along with
their forward-looking quarterly estimates, managers would be able to focus
more on sustainable, long-term corporate growth and less on meeting the
market’s short-term expectations, and institutional investors would have a
roadmap to hold corporations accountable for sustainable performance.
8
Make it easier for large corporations to become benefit corporations and
commit to fair treatment of their workers, consumers, society, and the
environment.
o Recently, the Business Roundtable made a promising statement recognizing
that businesses have a responsibility to treat all their stakeholders well and
to be socially responsible citizens. Skepticism exists about whether that
statement is just talk. One concrete way business leaders can move from
rhetoric to fairer treatment for workers, consumers, and the communities that
their businesses affect is for the Business Roundtable to support having their
corporations adopt the Benefit Corporation model. This model, which has
been adopted by the leading corporate state of Delaware, requires, by use of
the word “shall” and other means, that the corporation treat all stakeholders
fairly, even in a sale of the corporation. The model is conservative in that
the only constituency with a vote remains the stockholders, and thus their
support for social responsibility is what keeps the board accountable. To
move toward this sensible model, however, unreasonable barriers must be
removed that require a supermajority vote or create a right to appraisal if a
corporation is to opt into the Benefit Corporation model or if a corporation
merges into an existing Benefit Corporation. There is no principled basis for
this discrimination against Benefit Corporations, as the Benefit Corporation
model contains all the strong fiduciary and statutory protections against self-
dealing and unfair treatment available under corporate laws like Delaware’s.
A majority vote of stockholders to move to Benefit Corporation model
should be enough. And, if the Business Roundtable, institutional investors,
and policy makers get behind this principled approach, entrepreneurs would
have far less reason to argue for giving themselves stock with special voting
power to protect other stakeholders, because a one-share, one vote model
would exist that requires fair treatment of stakeholders.
Strengthening Institutional Investors’ Obligations to Promote Sustainable, Long-
Term Growth and Serve the Interests of Human Investors
Requiring operating companies to make EESG disclosures is a good start, but inadequate
step. We cannot expect companies to focus on creating long-term sustainable value for
workers, investors, and other stakeholders if those who elect the board and vote on
management’s compensation are more focused on the next quarter than the company’s
ability to generate durable returns. Because Americans must give their retirement and
college savings to institutional investors, institutional investors now dominate the
governance of public corporations. These institutional investors should be required to use
their voting power in a way that is aligned with the interests of the worker-investors whose
retirement and college savings money they control. Institutional investors should be
expected to consider the need these worker-investors have for sustainable wealth creation,
9
and their interests as human beings who need our economy to produce good jobs that pay
good wages and to generate wealth in a way that does not harm the environment or
consumers.
But requiring institutional investors to account for the investment objectives and human
realities of their worker-investors is not enough if they do not have information about the
other investorstypically activist investorsmaking proposals to change a company’s
strategic direction. Requiring these activist investors to disclose more information about
their positions and the nature of their capital is therefore necessary for the corporate
electorate to make an informed vote on these significant decisions. And finally, attention
should also be paid to so-called “private funds,” such as hedge funds and private equity
funds, which are often able to escape giving full disclosure to investors, despite taking
money from pension funds that many Americans rely on for retirement and from
universities and charities that advance important, publicly subsidized purposes.
The Fair and Sustainable Capitalism Proposal would:
Require institutional investors to consider their ultimate beneficiaries’ specific
investment objectives and horizons, such as saving for retirement or education,
as part of their fiduciary duties, and empower institutional investors to
consider their ultimate beneficiaries’ economic and human interest in having
companies create quality jobs, and act ethically and responsibly toward their
consumers and the environment.
o To start, institutional investors’ fiduciary duties must be modified to both
impose additional accountability and free institutions to consider their
beneficiaries’ interests as human beings who are not just investors, but
workers, parents, breathers of air, and citizens. Currently, the funds that
Americans are invested in do not have to vote in a way that is tailored to the
specific investment objectives of the funds and their investors. That is,
instead of considering the particular investment horizon or financial needs of
the investors in each fund, the funds in the same fund family (e.g.,
BlackRock, Vanguard, Fidelity, etc.) all tend to vote the same way. But most
worker-investors are rational index fund investors. And, an index fund will
not exit until the portfolio stock leaves the index because its investment
strategy requires it to hold all stocks in the index. Too often, index funds do
not vote this unique stuck-in perspective. Rather, the index fund will vote
the same way as the actively traded funds in the fund complex, regardless of
the fact that the active funds do not hold their investments for the long-term,
and regardless of key factors such as whether the issue on the table is a stock-
for-stock merger in which the index fund holds both the acquirer and the
target. This situation must change if corporations are to be responsive to the
flesh and blood human beings who provide their capital. Requiring
10
institutional investors to consider the investment horizons and objectives of
their ultimate beneficiaries will align institutional investors’ voting behavior
with the interest of the human investors whose capital they manage.
o Not only that, but proxy advisors remain highly influential in our corporate
governance system. If institutional investors are going to vote with the
interests of their ultimate beneficiaries in mind, then institutional investors
must not rely on proxy advisory firm recommendations unless the proxy
advisor’s recommendations are tailored to the fund’s investment style and
horizon. This requirement would create incentives for proxy advisory firms
to do better; and in particular, encourage them to develop voting
recommendations and policies tailored to index investors, who are uniquely
long-term and committed to sustainable wealth creation.
o Under the Proposal, large institutional investors who take human investors’
money, including mutual funds and pension funds, would be required to
consider the specific investment objectives and horizons of their ultimate
beneficiaries, such as saving for retirement, saving for their children’s
education, or investing in a socially responsible manner, when making voting
and other stewardship decisions. Specific obligations would be imposed on
index and pension funds that would have to consider their investors’ interests
in sustainable, long-term growth and the diversified nature of their portfolios.
o As important, any covered institutional investor would be authorized to
consider their ultimate beneficiaries’ overall economic and human welfare,
including their interests as workers, taxpayers, consumers, and human beings
who live in the environment, in determining how to prudently invest their
funds for sustainable, ethical portfolio growth. This plain and simple
authorization for investment funds to consider EESG factors will eliminate
any fear that institutional investors cannot take into account the moral and
ethical factors that human investors can consider. This will help align
institutional investors’ voting and stewardship practices with the interests of
the human investors who give these institutions money every paycheck.
Require institutional investors to explain how their voting policies and other
stewardship practices ensure the faithful discharge of their new fiduciary
duties and take into account the new information reported by large companies
on employee, environmental, social, and governance matters.
o To ensure investors and regulators that institutional investors are voting and
engaging with operating companies in a way that serves the interests of the
human investors whose money they manage, the new fiduciary obligations
11
imposed on institutional investors should be accompanied by parallel
disclosure requirements.
o Accordingly, the Proposal would require the Securities and Exchange
Commission and the Department of Labor, in consultation with the
Department of Commerce, the Department of Justice, and the Environmental
Protection Agency, to develop rules requiring covered institutional investors
to make annual disclosures explaining how their voting policies and other
stewardship practices (i) address the Proposal’s newly imposed fiduciary
duties; (ii) account for the information that the Proposal requires large
companies to disclose about their worker, environmental, social, and
governance impact; and (iii) address the specific objectives of the
institutional investors’ ultimate beneficiaries. This required disclosure
would also have parallels with the disclosure obligations imposed on
operating companies.
Close loopholes so that activist hedge funds have to make a full and timely
disclosure of their economic interests in the companies they seek to influence.
o If institutional investors are to effectively represent their beneficiaries’ long-
term interests, they need up-to-date information about those making
proposals affecting corporations’ business plans and corporate governance
rules. Over the last two decades, the model of shareholder engagement has
changed profoundly. In the past, shareholders commonly did not seek to
pressure companies to take actions that changed fundamental corporate
business plans and strategies in a way that affected other shareholders and,
most important, employees. But today, shareholderstypically activist
hedge fundsoften seek influence to do just that. These shareholders pose
substantial risks for other shareholders, especially long-term capital
providers like the institutional investors who hold the retirement savings of
worker-investors. These activists also affect the interest of company
employees, whose livelihood can be put in danger by risky proposals to pump
up immediate profits in an unsustainable way. It is up to the entire corporate
electorate to consider the proposals of activists, but because the electorate
cannot do so effectively without accurate and up-to-date information on
activist investors incentives, economic interests in the companies they invest
in, capital position, and holding periods.
o Under current law, activist investors who seek to influence management
such as activist hedge fundsare already required to make a special
“Schedule 13D” filing with the Securities and Exchange Commission once
they acquire 5% of the company’s stock so that their interest in the company
is known to other investors. But various loopholes have allowed activist
12
investors to avoid making full and timely disclosure of their interests. If
institutional investors are going to rationally consider activist investors’
proposed changes to a company’s strategic direction, more information about
the activists’ economic interests and how they align with the interests of the
company’s long-term human investors is needed. If, for example, an activist
is arguing for a company to cut its capital expenditures and pay a special
dividend, but the activist is contractually required to sell its stock in three
years because its fund must liquidate, the other shareholders are entitled to
know about that. And because the current disclosure regime dates from the
1960s and was not designed to address the market developments that have
allowedthrough techniques such as derivatives and all-day tradingthe
aggregation of influential blocks of stock before the public markets know
what is going on, the SEC’s current rule must be changed to prevent activists
from gaining creeping control without paying a control premium before
disclosing their proposal to management and other investors. This will bring
the United States current with other markets such as the European Union.
o To close the existing loopholes, the Proposal would require the Securities
and Exchange Commission to revise its rules governing Schedule 13D
disclosures so that: (i) the definition of beneficial ownership would include
ownership of any derivative instrument that provides the opportunity to profit
from an increase in the value of the subject security and any contract or
device that allows the person to control the voting power of the equity
security; (ii) any activist investor required to file a Schedule 13D would also
be required to disclose any short interest or ownership of a derivative
instrument that allows the investor to profit from a decrease in the security’s
value; (iii) any 13D filer would be prohibited from acquiring additional
shares (or derivatives) once the investor crosses the 5% threshold (for large-
cap companies) or a 10% threshold (for smaller companies) until a 13D has
been filed and available to the public for 24 hours; and (iv) any 13D filer
would be required to disclose any contractual or other arrangement that
relates to the filer’s commitment or ability to hold the subject security,
including the ability of the filer’s investors, if any, to redeem or withdrawal
their capital. Additionally, the “investment-only” exception to the Hart
ScottRodino filing requirements would be revised for Schedule 13D and
13G filers so that HartScottRodino filings do not function as a substitute
for 13D and 13G filings for transactions that do not pose meaningful antitrust
concerns.
13
Require an SEC study on the investor protection risks from private funds that
are subject to only limited disclosure requirements.
o Under current law, hedge funds and private equity funds may solicit the
investment of any “accredited investor” without providing meaningful or
standardized disclosure about the fund’s or manager’s past performance or
other risks. This accredited investor exception was originally intended as a
sort of “Thurston Howell” exception, because that iconic figure from
Gilligan’s Island comes to mind as the sort of rich person policymakers
believed could proceed at his own risk. Put simply, the idea was that if
hugely rich people wanted to risk their wealth, they could. That exception
was never intended to allow funds on which ordinary Americans depend for
their pensions, universities that educate our children, or key charitable
institutions like the Red Cross and Boys & Girls Clubs of America to be able
to put money at risk in investments not backed up by appropriate disclosures
and standards of integrity. But today, pension funds, university endowments,
and charities can qualify as accredited investors (and “qualified purchasers,”
which are effectively “super” accredited investors, under the laws governing
investment funds), thus ultimately exposing human investors to the risks that
come with hedge fund and private equity fund investing. Nothing is
intrinsically wrong with the private equity or hedge fund business model, but
problems have arisen when pension funds that workers rely on for their
retirement or charitable institutions endowed to provide critical social
services invest in opaque private funds without adequate disclosure. These
losses hurt workers and society and can require taxpayers to fill the resulting
holes. Absent appropriate and reliable disclosure around past performance,
the fees charged to all the funds’ investors, and the basic strategy and
holdings of the fund, pension funds and charities too often entrust their
beneficiaries hard-earned capital without enough information to prudently
assess whether the investment is appropriate for their portfolio on both a risk-
return basis and on a cost basis. Of course, disclosure should be tailored to
the fund’s investments, e.g., hedge funds should not be required to disclose
proprietary information about their trading strategies to the public. But
pension funds and large charity endowments need enough reliable
information to make informed investment decisions.
o Under the Proposal, the Securities and Exchange Commission would be
required to submit a study to Congress on the investor protection risks and
benefits of private funds that are subject to only limited disclosure
requirements, such as hedge funds and private equity funds. This study
would have to include (i) an assessment of the adequacy of the disclosures
that such private funds provide to their investors; (ii) an assessment of
whether fund managers are adequately and reliably disclosing their
14
performance history; (iii) an assessment of the fees charged by these
investment managers and whether certain classes of investors are paying
more to access these investments; (iv) an assessment of how frequently fund
managers offer superior investment terms to certain favored investors and
whether disclosure about those favorable terms is available to other
investors; and (v) an assessment of whether the universe of accredited
investors and qualified purchasers is appropriately defined to include only
sophisticated investors who can fend for themselves. The study would also
include recommendations about whether additional regulation or legal
authority is needed to address these concerns.
Reforming the Corporate Electoral System to Promote Sustainable, Long-Term
Growth
Reforms at the operating company and institutional investor level must be accompanied by
reforms to the corporate electoral system. If we want institutional investors to wisely focus
their voting decisions on sustainable corporate performance, we must reduce the continual
mini-referendums occurring each year and the huge number of votes shareholders must
cast each year, which encourages companies to manage to the changing whims of the stock
market and institutional investors to outsource voting decisions to proxy advisory firms.
With fewer but more meaningful votes, we can have a vibrant accountability system better
focused on whether corporations are producing profits in a socially responsible manner.
To that end, the Fair and Sustainable Capitalism Proposal would:
Change the “say-on-pay” voting system to promote more thoughtful voting by
requiring companies to hold shareholder votes on executive compensation once
every four years (or sooner upon any material change in executive
compensation) and present shareholders with a four-year plan for each vote.
o One impediment to thoughtful voting is the substantial number of “say-on-
pay” votes on executive compensationover 2,000 per yearthat
institutional investors must cast at U.S. public companies every year.
Because executive compensation should be designed to provide top
executives with appropriate incentives to manage well and create sustainable
long-term increases in corporate value, it is counterproductive that
compensation arrangements should run on annual terms, with constant
tinkering and changing of key provisions. Rather, compensation committees
should bargain for and set employment contracts with a meaningful length
over which to assess the contribution of management to the corporation.
Likewise, if shareholders are going to be given voice in those arrangements,
their voice should be exercised in a mature fashion consistent with the actual
arrangements that will be binding on the corporation and with their sensible
length. No one who cares about America’s worker-investors believes that
15
corporate executives should be paid based on year-to-year incentives.
Rather, they should be rewarded for helping to create sustainable corporate
profits, and their pay contracts should therefore be long term in nature. But
instead of voting on long-term pay plans on a sensible schedule, say-on-pay
votes are held annually, and likely because of the overwhelming number of
these annual say-on-pay votes, academic research has found that institutional
investors often rely heavily on proxy advisory firms in their voting on these
resolutions (with less than ideal consequences). CEO pay continues to rise
faster than the pay of company employees overall, and recent research
bolsters the view that the current system of annual say-on-pay voting isn’t
working to close that gap.
o To mitigate these problems and allow more thoughtful voting by institutional
investors, the Proposal would change the “say-on-pay” requirements
imposed on public companies by the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and
Consumer Protection Act so that companies would be required to hold a say-
on-pay vote every four years, or sooner if there is any material change in the
terms of the executive compensation, based on a pay plan covering at least
the next four-year period. The SEC would be required to establish a schedule
so that approximately 25% of public companies have a pay vote each year,
allowing for informed voting on a four-year track record rationally related to
sustainable performance. Ultimately, this would result in more thoughtful
voting by shareholders, helping to realize the vision that Congress originally
had for say-on-pay votes.
Modify the SEC’s shareholder proposal rule to require proponents of economic
shareholder proposals to have a genuine stake in the company and modestly
increase resubmissions thresholds so that proposals that repeatedly fail by
large margins are left off the ballot in future years.
o Some modest changes to the rules governing shareholder proposals could
also encourage more thoughtful voting by institutional investors and increase
the benefit to cost ratio of the corporate voting process. Although the SEC’s
shareholder proposal rule likely plays a salutary role overall, some
proponentsespecially small-stakes proponents making economic
proposalshave been less than thoughtful in deciding which companies to
target for proposals, which recent academic research has found burdens the
system with unnecessary and value-destroying votes. That finding is
unsurprising: how actual end-user investors or corporate performance are
aided by having hundreds of poorly targeted votes each year is difficult to
understand. But what is certain is that institutional investors cannot
rationally focus on all of them, limiting their ability to spend energy and
attention on legitimate proposals that may benefit the corporation.
16
o These burdensome shareholder proposals are encouraged (or at least not
discouraged) by law, which currently allows a shareholder holding as little
as $2,000 in the company’s stock to make a proposal and have the company
(and thus other shareholders and constituents like company employees) pay
for the substantial costs of including the proposal on the corporate ballot and
responding to it, generating too many proposals by shareholders with little
stake in the company’s future and thereby overwhelming the capacity of the
investors voting on those proposals to meaningfully inform themselves as to
the proposals’ merits. This should not be so. In most states, candidates for
public office are required to pay a reasonable filing fee tied to a percentage
of the salary of the office they seek. And, California requires a $2,000 filing
fee for ballot initiatives. It is reasonable and productive to ask the same of
investors who seek to change the business plans or governance of a company.
Requiring sponsors of economic proposals filed under Rule 14a-8 to pay a
reasonable filing fee to bear a tiny fraction of the much larger costs their
proposal will impose on the corporation, and therefore other shareholders
and corporate constituents like workers, is a responsible method to better
recalibrate the benefitcost ratio of the shareholder proposal rule.
o Accordingly, the Proposal would require the Securities and Exchange
Commission to revise its shareholder proposal rule so that shareholders
seeking to make an “economic” shareholder proposal, such as a proposal
requesting the removal of takeover defenses, at company expense would
need to hold the lesser of $2 million or 1% of the company’s stock (with
proponents having the option to aggregate their shares with any other
shareholders willing to join in the proposal to satisfy the ownership
requirement). This is an achievable number that shows that the proponents
have a serious enough stake to justify the costs the proposal will have for
others. It is like the requirement in states like California to get support from
at least 5% of voters before a ballot institute goes forward, but is by
comparison far easier and less costly to achieve. Additionally, the Proposal
would require a proponent of an economic proposal to pay a $2,000 fee to
have the proposal placed on the corporate ballot. These two requirements
would not apply to environmental and social proposals; thus, for example, a
proponent of a resolution encouraging the company to take action on climate
change would be exempt from the new eligibility requirements. Finally, the
Proposal would modestly increase the thresholds at which all proposals that
fail to gain a meaningful share of the vote can be excluded in later years.
Currently, a proposal that gets as little as 3% of the vote can still be included
in later years; under the Proposal, a proposal would be excludable if it fails
to gain 5% in the first year, 10% in the second year, or 20% in the third year.
This clock would reset after five years. And this change would help investors
17
to focus more on assessing the merits of the proposals that are likely to
actually gain wide support, and prevent idiosyncratic shareholders from
repeatedly costing other shareholders and corporate constituents time and
money over a proposal that has not garnered any substantial level of support.
Require shareholders attempting to change a company’s corporate
governanceeither by making shareholder proposals or soliciting proxiesto
disclose their economic interest in the company.
o If institutional investors representing American worker-investors are going
to rationally consider shareholder proposals or proxy challenges, more
information is needed about those who are making these proposals. Investors
cannot fully consider an activist’s proposal if the investor does not know
whether the activist making the proposal has a genuine, long-term interest in
the company’s sustainable profitability. Activist shareholders who seek
changes in a company’s business plans or a breakup of the business have a
huge impact on company employees and other shareholders. The
institutional investors who hold the capital of working Americans should
have better information to know if the activists’ economic interests are
aligned with the interests of patient investors such as index investors and
others who hold stock for the long run.
o To that end, the Proposal would require those making shareholder proposals
or soliciting proxies to disclosure in clear and standard form their net
beneficial ownership interest in the company’s securities. Disclosure of their
beneficial ownership interest would include any short interest or ownership
of any derivative instrument or any contract or device that allows the person
to control the voting power of the equity security.
Updating Our Tax System to Reduce Speculation, Address Climate Change, and
Promote Sustainable Growth, Innovation, and Job Creation
In tandem with reforms to operating company disclosure, institutional investors, and the
proxy system, our tax system must also be reformed to provide the right incentives for
companies and investors to focus on promoting sustainable, long-term growth. Adoption
of a sensible fractional trading tax on all securities transactions, including transactions by
401(k) investors, and capital gains reform to make eligibility for the preferential long-term
rate dependent on actual long-term investment would help all investors focus more on
sustainable returns. Not only that, but taxes like these discourage unproductive and
destabilizing speculation of the kind that contributed to the financial crisis. In addition, tax
changes applicable to hedge fund managers’ compensation can place everyone on the same
playing field, ensure that the labor income produced by private equity and hedge fund
18
executives is taxed on the same basis as the sweat put in by other American workers, and
help ensure that Wall Street pays its fair share of taxes. Not only that, but these taxes can
help close a deficit that has widened after the passage of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017
while also providing necessary funds for investment in infrastructure modernization,
tackling climate change, cutting-edge research and development to secure America’s
position as a global leader in innovation and the industries of the future, and workplace
training to ensure that American workers are ready to tackle this century’s technological
challenges and have quality jobs. To accomplish these goals, the Fair and Sustainable
Capitalism Proposal would:
Change the holding period for long-term capital gains from one year to five.
o Currently, an investment needs to be held for only one year to be considered
“long term,” which allows short-term investors to take advantage of the
preferential low tax rate for genuine, long-term capital gains.
o The Proposal would change this period to five years, thereby helping to
promote long-term investment and discourage harmful speculation.
Establish a financial transaction tax.
o The Proposal would impose a very modest tax on most financial transactions,
including the trading of stocks, mutual funds, bonds, and derivatives. This
small tax would moderate excessive speculation, curb uneconomic high-
frequency trading with no fundamental investment rationale that can
contribute to financial system instability, encourage more thoughtful long-
term investing, and discourage irrational fund-hopping by mutual fund
consumers. All these incentives will help institutional investors as well as
mutual funds better concentrate on stable investment strategies focused on
sustainable growththe kind that allows for fair gainsharing with company
workers and provides funds for investors when they retire. Estimated to
generate over $2 trillion over 10 years, this tax should be used as a down-
payment on important, long-term investments in sustainable growth. A
financial transaction tax has been supported by leading economists such as
Nobel Prize winner Joseph Stiglitz.
o The rate for this tax would be 0.5% for equity securities, 0.1% for bonds, and
0.005% for derivatives.
Close the carried interest loophole.
o Under current law, some of the nation’s wealthiest individualshedge fund
and private equity managerspay a lower tax rate than average Americans
19
because the bulk of their income is taxed at the preferential 20% long-term
capital gains tax rate as so-called “carried interest,” rather than at the ordinary
income tax rate of 37%, even though they are effectively being paid for their
labor. Ensuring our system works for all also requires eliminating this unfair
tax advantage hedge funds get over other human laborers. Closing this
loophole would also diminish the ability of hedge fund managers to reap
profits not shared with their investors and their targets’ other shareholders in
the long-run, thereby shifting the activist hedge fund market directionally
toward those fund managers able to generate value by contributing
managerial expertise that creates durable value for the public companies in
its portfolio. And because the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act of 2017 gave the
majority of its tax breaks to wealthier Americans and increased the federal
deficit substantially, closing the carried interest loophole is a fairer and more
productive way to restore some equity to the Tax Code, while also helping
to reduce the deficit or provide for other important national needs.
o The Proposal would close the carried interest loophole by requiring private
equity or hedge fund managers’ compensationin whatever formbe taxed
as income, not as capital gains.
Create an Infrastructure, Innovation, and Human Capital Trust Fund.
o It is no secret that our nation currently lags in infrastructure and research
spending, hurting the ability of American businesses to compete globally,
and there has been bipartisan consensus that these problems need to be
addressed.
o To ensure that the funds raised by the financial transaction tax are used to
promote sustainable development, the Proposal would transfer all the
revenue raised by the financial transaction tax into a newly created
Infrastructure, Innovation, and Human Capital Trust Fund. Congress could
spend capital in the trust fund on only basic research and development,
revitalizing our nation’s infrastructure in an environmentally responsible
way that helps us redress climate change, and workplace training. In
particular, as the United States transitions to less carbon intensive energy
production, those in carbon-intensive industries will require help
transitioning their high quality skills to the evolving skills needed to work
with these new energy technologies. To that end, the funds in the
Infrastructure, Innovation, and Human Capital Trust Fund could be used to
provide training, support, and other assistance to help employees working in
carbon-intensive industries transition to quality employment in industries
generating energy in non-carbon intensive ways and to other emerging
industries. This $2 trillion investment over the next 10 years can help create
20
a sustainable, carbon-efficient transportation system and electrical grid, and
aid the development of next-generation energy solutions, among other long-
term, sustainable projects, while creating thousands of well-paying jobs that
cannot be shipped overseas.
Curbing Corporate Power and Leveling the Playing Field for Workers, Consumers,
and Investors
Lastly, we must address three sets of challenges created in no small part by the United
States Supreme Court, which have amplified corporate power at the expense of American
workers, consumers, and human investors. In the 2010 decision Citizens United v. Federal
Election Commission striking down the Bipartisan Campaign Reform Act (McCain-
Feingold), the Supreme Court unleashed a massive growth in unchecked corporate political
spending, which major institutional investors have so far been unwilling to addresseven
though the human investors whose money they manage do not invest their money so it can
be spent by corporations on politics. And in a series of decisions blessing the increased
use of forced arbitration, the Supreme Court has allowed businesses to deny workers,
consumers, and human investors their day in court and has blocked the States from
exercising their sovereign right to decide how best to enforce their own laws. Finally, in
recent decisions such as Harris v. Quinn and Janus v. American Federation of State,
County, and Municipal Employees, Council 31, the U.S. Supreme Court has added to the
difficulties for American workers seeking to exercise in an effective way their right to form
a union and collectively bargain. These adverse decisions came on top of existing statutory
roadblocks to a majority of workers being able to seek greater gainsharing through
collective bargaining.
Other proposals, such as the Do No Harm Act, should also be enacted to address the
amplification of corporate power, and diminution in the rights of working people to receive
minimum federally guaranteed benefits of employment, condoned by Burwell v. Hobby
Lobby. But, to address the problems identified above, the Fair and Sustainable Capitalism
Proposal would:
Prohibit public companies from spending money on politics without the
consent of at least 75% of their shareholders.
o Human investors do not invest their money for corporate executives to spend
it on politics. We know this because this is not how institutional investors
advertise to attract investors, and because human investors are as diverse as
the nation and there is no rational reason to believe they have similar views
on political issues. Corporate political spending also harms human investors
seeking long-term sustainable earnings. Businesses that have to lobby and
rent-seek to get ahead are less profitable. Not only that, but as most human
21
investors invest through index funds, any benefit that does accrue to one
company through political lobbying is offset by harms to another and washes
out for the index investor who holds the market. As important, worker-
investors are taxpayers, and it hits the economic bottom line if businesses can
externalize costs of ethical, sustainable ways of doing business to the public
in the form of environmental harm that must be cleaned up or injured workers
or consumers.
o To ensure that human investors’ money is not being spent on politics without
their consent, the Proposal would bar public companies from making any
disbursement for a political purpose without first obtaining the consent,
either for that specific disbursement or under a general policy allowing
disbursements of that type, of at least 75% of their shareholders. This
provision tracks a proposal by the late John Bogle, the respected founder of
the index fund giant Vanguard.
Enhance fairness and restore State sovereignty over the enforceability of
forced arbitration clauses.
o The United States Supreme Court has interpreted the Federal Arbitration Act
to apply to a broad range of disputes to which it was not originally intended
to apply, such as disputes between workers and their employers, thereby
denying American workers and consumers their day in court by funneling
them into secretive arbitration proceedings. This is especially problematic
for consumer disputes that are important but not worth enough for a lawyer
to take on the case unless consumers are allowed to join together in a class
action. Moreover, this expansive interpretation of the Federal Arbitration
Actwhich has applied to not only lawsuits arising under Federal law, but
also lawsuits arising under State lawhas blocked the States from
determining how to best enforce their own laws.
o To stop the unfair application of the Federal Arbitration Act to disputes to
which Congress never intended it to apply and restore State sovereignty so
that the States can determine for themselves how their own laws should be
enforced, the Fair and Sustainable Capitalism Proposal would amend the
Federal Arbitration Act so that: (i) for employment, consumer, antitrust,
securities, internal affairs, and civil rights disputes that arise under Federal
law, forced arbitration clauses would be enforceable only if applicable
Federal law other than the Federal Arbitration Act (such as the Fair Labor
Standards Act or some other substantive law) makes them enforceable; and
(ii) for employment, consumer, antitrust, securities, internal affairs, and civil
rights disputes that arise under State law, forced arbitration clauses would be
enforceable only if applicable State law makes them enforceable.
22
Reform the union election progress by permitting card check elections to make
it easier for workers to organize and collectively bargain with their employers.
o Reforming the corporate election process is a strong start on the path to
increased gainsharing between workers and corporations. But to restore
shared prosperity and create an economy that benefits all Americans,
working Americans also need the ability to collectively organize and bargain
with their employers. At least since the Reagan Administration, the ability
of American workers to use the rights guaranteed by the National Labor
Relations Act (“NLRA”) has been increasingly compromised. As a result,
the leverage of American workers to obtain fair pay has been weakened,
contributing to growing inequality and a decline in fair gain sharing between
corporations and their workers. Labor’s declining influence has only been
further eroded by recent decisions of the U.S. Supreme Court, such as Janus
v. American Federation of State, County, and Municipal Employees and
Harris v. Quinn, that treat labor unions in a disfavored manner in comparison
to corporations in the area of political spending, and that have now gone
further and denied unions the right to obtain fair payments from workers they
advocate for in pay negotiations and protect from unfair discharge or
demotions. The important reforms contained in the Protecting the Right to
Organize Act should become law to address this diminution in worker voice.
But an additional important step should be taken. Current law hinders
workers’ ability to organize because even after a majority of workers signs a
petition or authorization card supporting unionization (informally known as
“card check”), a company can still demand a formal, time-consuming
election during which the company can seek to erode the union’s support and
delay collective bargaining. That is, even after a majority of employees
support unionization, an employer can delay its formation and potentially
avoid unionization all together by pressuring workers during the secret ballot
campaign. Unsurprisingly, studies suggest that unionization rates are higher
when unions are recognized after a majority of workers sign a petition
supporting unionization, and union members enjoy higher wages and more
robust benefits packages compared to non-union workforces.
o If we are to improve the wages of American workers, the effectiveness of the
NLRA’s promise to American workers needs to be renewed by granting
unions obtaining a fair showing of majority support recognition and the right
to bargain on behalf of the workforce for fair wages and working conditions.
23
Acknowledgements
The Fair and Sustainable Capitalism Proposal was influenced by the scholarship and thinking of
many distinguished elected officials, public servants, academics, and thought leaders. A debt of
gratitude is owed to all of them for their research and thinking on making our economy work better
for all. Among the many sources considered and consulted in the preparation of the Proposal were:
Accountable Capitalism Act, S. 3348, 115th Cong. (2018).
Forced Arbitration Injustice Repeal Act, S. 610, 116th Cong. (2019).
Brokaw Act, S. 1744, 115th Cong. (2017).
Do No Harm Act of 2019, S. 593, 116th Cong. (2019).
Employer Free Choice Act of 2016, H.R. 5000, 114th Cong. (2016).
Inclusive Prosperity Act of 2019, S. 1587, 116th Cong. (2019).
Shareholders United Act of 2019, H.R. 936, 116th Cong. (2019).
Wall Street Tax Act of 2019, S. 647, 116th Cong. (2019).
To amend the Internal Revenue Code of 1986 to treat income received by partners for
performing investment management services as ordinary income received for the
performance of services, H.R. 2834, 110th Cong. (2007).
Frederick H. Alexander, Comment on SEC File Number S7-06-16 Concept Release:
Business and Financial Disclosure Required by Regulation S-K (July 14, 2016).
ELIZABETH ANDERSON, PRIVATE GOVERNMENT: HOW EMPLOYERS RULE OUR LIVES (AND
WHY WE DONT TALK ABOUT IT) (2017).
Tim Armour et al., Commonsense Corporate Governance Principles, Commonsense Corp.
Governance Principles.
The Aspen Institute, Overcoming Short-Termism: A Call for a More Responsible
Approach to Investment and Business Management (Sept. 9, 2009).
The Aspen Institute, American Prosperity Project: A Nonpartisan Framework for Long-
Term Investment (Dec. 19, 2016).
The Aspen Institute, Toward a New Capitalism: The Promise of Opportunity and the
Future of Work (Jan. 12, 2017).
Lucian Bebchuk & Robert J. Jackson, Jr., Corporate Political Speech: Who Decides?, 124
HARV. L. REV. 83 (2010).
Lucian A. Bebchuk & Robert J. Jackson, Jr., Shining Light on Corporate Political
Spending, 101 GEORGETOWN L. J. 923 (2013).
Lucian Bebchuk & Scott Hirst, Index Funds and the Future of Corporate Governance:
Theory, Evidence, and Policy 119 COLUM. L. REV. (Forthcoming 2019).
Lucian A. Bebchuk, et al., The Untenable Case for Keeping Investors in the Dark, Lucian
A. Bebchuk, et al., The Untenable Case for Keeping Investors in the Dark, 10 HARV. BUS.
L. REV. (Forthcoming 2020).
John C. Coates IV & Taylor Lincoln, Fulfilling Kennedy’s Promise: Why the SEC Should
Mandate Disclosure of Corporate Political Activity (Working Paper, Sept. 8, 2011).
John C. Coates IV, Corporate Politics, Governance, and Value Before and After Citizens
United, 9 J. EMPIRICAL LEGAL STUD. 657 (2012).
John C. Coates IV, Corporate Speech & The First Amendment: History, Data and
Implications, 30 CONST. COMM. 223 (2015).
24
John C. Coates, IV, The Future of Corporate Governance Part I: The Problem of Twelve,
Harv. Pub. L. Working Paper No. 19-07 (Mar. 14, 2019).
Madison Condon, Externalities and the Common Owner, Wash. L. Rev. (forthcoming
2020).
COUNCIL ON FOREIGN RELATIONS, INDEPENDENT TASK FORCE REPORT NO.
77, INNOVATION AND NATIONAL SECURITY: KEEPING OUR EDGE (2019).
Adam O. Emmerich et al., Fair Markets and Fair Disclosure: Some Thoughts on the Law
and Economics of Blockholder Disclosure, and the Use and Abuse of Shareholder Power,
3 HARV. BUS. L. REV. 135 (2013).
Jan Fichtner, Eelke M. Heemskerk & Javier Garcia-Bernardo, Hidden Power of the Big
Three? Passive Index Funds, Re-concentration of Corporate Ownership, and New
Financial Risk, 19 BUS. & POL. 298 (2017).
Financial Reporting Council, The UK Corporate Governance Code (July 2018).
Jill E. Fisch & Cynthia A. Williams, Petition for Rulemaking Pursuant to Rule 192(a) (Oct.
1, 2018)
G20/OECD High-Level Principles of Long-Term Investment Financing by Institutional
Investors, Org. For Econ. Co-operation & Dev. (Sept. 2013).
Angela Hanks, et al., Workers or Waste? How Companies Discloseor Do Not Disclose
Human Capital Investment and What to Do About It, CTR. AM. PROGRESS (June 2016).
Ronald J. Gilson & Jeffrey N. Gordon, The Agency Costs of Agency Capitalism: Activist
Investors and the Revaluation of Governance Rights, 113 COLUM. L. REV. 863 (2013).
Andy Green & Andrew Schwartz, Corporate Long-Termism, Transparency, and the Public
Interest, CTR. AM. PROGRESS (Oct. 2018).
Zohar Goshen & Richard Squire, Principal Costs: A New Theory for Corporate Law and
Governance, 117 COLUM. L. REV. 767 (2017).
Ann Lipton, Not Everything Is About Investors: The Case for Mandatory Stakeholder
Disclosure, YALE J. ON REG. (Forthcoming 2020).
Martin Lipton et al., The New Paradigm: A Roadmap for an Implicit Corporate
Governance Partnership Between Corporations and Investors to Achieve Sustainable
Long-Term Investment and Growth, WORLD ECON. F. (Sept. 2, 2016).
Ewan McGaughey, Democracy in America at Work: The History of Labor’s Vote in
Corporate Governance, 42 SEATTLE UNIV. L. REV. 697 (2019).
COLIN MAYER, PROSPERITY: BETTER BUSINESS MAKES THE GREATER
GOOD (2019).
Joseph E. Stiglitz, Reforming Taxation to Promote Growth and Equity, ROOSEVELT INST.
(May 28, 2014).
LYNN STOUT, THE SHAREHOLDER VALUE MYTH: HOW PUTTING SHAREHOLDERS FIRST
HARMS INVESTORS, CORPORATIONS AND THE PUBLIC (2017).
Leo E. Strine, Jr., Can We Do Better by Ordinary Investors? A Pragmatic Reaction to the
Dueling Ideological Mythologists of Corporate Law, 114 COLUM. L. REV. 449 (2014).
Leo E. Strine, Jr. Toward Common Sense and Common Ground? Reflections on the Shared
Interests of Managers and Labor in a More Rational System of Corporate Governance, 33
J. CORP. L. 4, 16 (2007).
25
Leo E. Strine, Jr., Securing Our Nation’s Economic Future: A Sensible, Nonpartisan
Agenda to Increase Long-Term Investment and Job Creation in the United States, 71 BUS.
LAW. 1081 (2016).
Leo E. Strine, Jr., Who Bleeds When the Wolves Bite? A Flesh-and-Blood Perspective on
Hedge Fund Activism and Our Strange Corporate Governance System, 126 YALE L. J.
1870 (2017).