Strategic Conformity in Affiliate Marketing
Itay Fainmesser
Xudong Zheng
February 29, 2024
Abstract
Affiliate marketing is a prevalent performance-based marketing model. For the most part,
retailers have formally transitioned from paying marketing affiliates pay-per-click to a pay-
per-purchase compensation model. Yet, some pay-per-click incentives remain in many affiliate
programs. Our results show that the remaining pay-per-click incentives give rise to a conflict
of interest between affiliates and consumers. On the one hand, consumer surplus is maximized
under affiliates’ recommendation conformity, i.e., when affiliates converge on a single product
in their recommendation profile. On the other hand, if affiliates are compensated significantly
per click, they achieve the highest aggregate payoffs by minimizing recommendation confor-
mity. Surprisingly, even if affiliates are compensated mostly per purchase and both consumers
and affiliates would benefit from recommendation conformity, a conformity equilibrium may not
exist. In contrast, a non-conformity equilibrium always exists. We characterize further how con-
sumers’ expected search length, affiliates’ product information accuracy, and consumers’ ability
to learn directly about products’ qualities affect market outcomes via its effect on the existence
of conformity equilibria. Finally, our results shed light on how a retailer can craft affiliates’
compensation structure to influence market outcomes.
Keywords: Affiliate marketing, Strategic conformity
The Johns Hopkins Carey Business School and The Department of Economics, The Johns Hopkins University,
Baltimore, MD 21202 (e-mail: itay fainmesser@jhu.edu)
The Department of Economics, The Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, MD 21218 (e-mail: [email protected])
1
1 Introduction
Affiliates are websites (e.g., Wirecutter, CNET), bloggers, and social media influencers, who pro-
mote a retailer’s product or service (Shopify 2024) using unique affiliate links—links that allow
tracking by the retailer. An affiliate directs a consumer to a product’s web page on the retailer’s
online platform, and is compensated based on the consumer’s action. Common compensation
models include pay-per-click (the retailer pays the affiliate for each click on an affiliate link by a
consumer) and pay-per-purchase (the retailer pays the affiliate for each purchase by a consumer
who is directed to the platform by the affiliate’s link). Affiliate marketing is becoming increasingly
important to consumers and retailers. Since its inception in the mid-90s, affiliate marketing has
experienced a 10% year-on-year growth, becoming an industry worth over 15.7 billion U.S. dollars
in 2023,
1
accounting for 16% of all internet orders globally (a staggering 53% of all sales on Amazon
came from affiliates).
2
As a result, it is not surprising that over 80 percent of retailers consider
affiliate marketing to be a key way to promote products and engage consumers (Jefferson 2016).
Yet despite the prominence of affiliate marketing in practice, scant research has focused on affiliates’
strategic product recommendations.
This paper develops a new model that captures three key features of affiliate marketing: (1) the
majority of pay-per-purchase affiliate programs use a “cookie duration” to provide affiliates with
pay-per-click-like incentives,
3
(2) consumers often contribute more clicks than purchases during
their search processes, and (3) consumers and affiliates may be more likely to be aware of some
prominent products ex ante (e.g., a running shoe from Nike) than of other less prominent products
(e.g., a running shoe from Hoka)—we refer to such prominent product as salient products, and to
affiliates’ tendency to converge in their recommendations and recommend the same salient product
1
Source: Printify, https://printify.com/blog/affiliate-marketing-trends/, accessed January 25,
2024.
2
Source: Demandsage, https://www.demandsage.com/affiliate-marketing-statistics/, accessed
January 25, 2024.
3
That is, once a consumer clicks on an affiliate link, a cookie is set, and the affiliate receives a commission for the
consumer’s first purchase on website within a specific time frame, typically from twenty-four hours to several months.
Notably, the affiliate receives a commission even if the consumer buys a different product than the one recommended.
2
as recommendation conformity.
4,5
We answer the following questions:
1. How is recommendation conformity related to other market outcomes, such as affiliates’ ag-
gregate profits and consumer surplus?
2. How does the affiliate program’s commission structure, in particular pay-per-purchase vs. pay-
per-click, affect affiliates’ recommendation conformity, and subsequently the related market
outcomes?
3. Does increasing the information that affiliates have on products’ qualities (e.g., by allowing
affiliates to test products) make affiliates’ recommendation conformity more or less likely?
4. How do features of consumers’ search, such as search duration and the ability to observe a
product’s quality, affect affiliates’ recommendation conformity?
Our analysis shows that two affiliates’ recommendation profiles are especially important when
it comes to welfare outcomes. In a non-conformity strategy profile, affiliates disregard the salient
product, and each recommends a non-salient product for which he received a high quality signal.
On the other extreme, in a conformity strategy profile, every affiliate who receives a high quality
signal for the salient product, recommends the salient product. A non-conformity equilibrium and
a conformity equilibrium are equilibria in which affiliates employ non-conformity and conformity
strategy profiles respectively.
Our first result shows that a conformity strategy profile always maximizes the (expected) Con-
sumer Surplus (CS). If affiliates’ compensation has a significant per-purchase component, then a
conformity strategy profile also maximizes affiliates’ aggregate expected payoff, or Affiliate Sur-
4
Our notion of conformity is distinct from the one studied in the (sequential) social learning literature on online
reviews (Moe and Trusov 2011, Moe and Schweidel 2012, Sridhar and Srinivasan 2012). In that literature reviewers
may observe earlier reviews and, through belief updating, have their opinions (and reviews) align with existing
reviews. In contrast, affiliates in our framework provide their recommendations simultaneously. That is, their
recommendation conformity is a strategic outcome based on affiliates’ focus on maximizing their expected earnings
given their compensation structure.
5
In our model, there are many ex-ante substitutable products, each of either high or low quality. One of the
products is “salient” in the following sense: Each affiliate observes signals that contains information on the quality of
the salient product and the qualities of a randomly selected sample of the non-salient products. That is, all affiliates
receive signals on the quality of the salient product, and it is highly unlikely that any two affiliates receive signals
on the quality of the same non-salient product. As a result, recommendation conformity on a non-salient product is
ruled-out.
3
plus (AS).
6
In that case, consumers and affiliates have aligned preferences for conformity. How-
ever, if affiliates’ compensation has a significant per-click component, then AS is maximized by
a non-conformity strategy profile.
7
In that case, consumers’ and affiliates’ preferences for payoff
maximization are polar opposites. That is, we provide a bang-bang result: either AS and CS are
maximized by the same recommendation strategy profile or by opposing ones.
To see why a conformity strategy profile always maximizes CS, note that a conformity strat-
egy profile aggregates the most accurate information about the quality of the salient product. If
the salient product receives many recommendations, it is very likely to be of high quality. The
consumer’s belief induces her to inspect it first and likely to make a purchase, thus ending her
costly search after one click. The relationship between conformity and AS is more subtle. On
the one hand, when affiliates are compensated heavily per purchase, they want to convert the
consumer’s clicks to purchases effectively, so that the consumer purchases with high probability
before stopping to search. On the other hand, when affiliates are compensated heavily per click,
they seek to maximize clicks, hence, they might prefer to risk the consumer stopping the search
without purchasing, if that means the consumer clicks on more links in expectations. The affiliates’
compensation threshold for preferring conformity over non-conformity depends on the consumer’s
expected search duration (in case of no purchase) and the accuracy of affiliates’ information on
product quality: (a) the shorter the expected search the better off affiliates are in focusing on a
conformity strategy profile that maximizes the probability of purchase, and (b) the more accurate
the affiliates’ information, the more certain they are that the search will end with a purchase, so
their focus shifts to maximizing clicks.
Our second and third results show that a non-conformity equilibrium always exists, whereas
the existence of a conformity equilibrium subtly depends on affiliates’ compensation. In fact, even
when both the consumer and the affiliates would benefit from affiliates’ conformity, a conformity
equilibrium may not exist, leading to a sub-optimal welfare outcome. Yet, when affiliates’ payoffs
are maximized with a non-conformity strategy profile, a conformity equilibrium can exist. This
suggests that conflict of interest built into the market structure may make it challenging for affiliates
to coordinate on an equilibrium that is good for them and they may, instead, end with a market
6
The same is true if the consumer is likely to abort the search quickly in the absence of a purchase, or if affiliates’
information about products’ qualities is likely inaccurate.
7
The same is true if the consumer is likely to continue searching for longer, or if affiliates’ information about
products’ qualities is sufficiently accurate.
4
outcome that is sub-optimal for them.
To see why a non-conformity equilibrium always exists, suppose that all but one affiliate recom-
mend non-salient products. In that case, the remaining affiliate will have no incentive to recommend
the salient product (regardless of his information about the salient product’s quality). The reason
is that salience leads the consumer to make quality inferences about the salient product based on
the absence of recommendations—if some affiliates do not recommend it, they might have learned
that the salient product has low quality. To the contrary, a conformity equilibrium may not exists
if either the incentives for affiliates to conform are two weak (for example if compensation is heavily
per click), or if their incentives to conform are too strong (for example if compensation is heavily
per purchase). In the case in which incentives to conform are too strong, if all other affiliates
employ conformity strategies, an affiliate would chose to recommend the salient product even if
he received a low quality signal for it—leading to the collapse of the equilibrium and unraveling
towards the non-conformity equilibrium.
An interesting implication of our results is that the retailer can affect when a conformity equi-
librium exists through its control of affiliates’ compensation, changing the weight between per-click
and per-purchase compensation. However, the effect of shifting compensation weights between
per-purchase and per-click is not straightforward and depends on the consumer’s expected search
duration in the following way: If a consumer is likely to abandon the search early, her first click-
through is more critical to affiliates than the prospect of subsequent clicks. Hence, when affiliates
are paid per-click, a conformity equilibrium exists for a larger set of parameters. In contrast, when
the consumer’s expected search is longer, affiliates are less sensitive to the first click. As a re-
sult, if consumer search is expected to be longer, a heavier pay-per-click component implies that a
conformity equilibrium exists for a smaller set of parameters.
We generalize our model to accommodate an environment in which the consumer cannot per-
fectly observe the true quality of a product after clicking on an affiliate link, but instead she observes
a noisy signal. We show that our results extend to this more general environment. The more gen-
eral model also allows us to derive additional comparative statics. Interestingly, in the limit case of
experience goods, where consumers do not observe any independent quality signal before purchase,
affiliates as a group become indifferent between conformity and non-conformity strategy profiles,
and a conformity equilibrium exists for a smaller range of parameters.
5
Our paper continues as follows. We discuss our contribution to the literature in the remaining
of Section 1. Section 2 presents our baseline model. In Section 3, we present our results highlighting
the conflict of interest between affiliates and consumers, and characterize the existence of conformity
equilibria. Section 4 presents an extension generalizing the assumption on the consumer’s learning
and discusses implications for platform design. All proofs are deferred to the appendix.
1.1 Related Literature
Our paper contributes to the literature on social influencers. Katona (2020) analyzes how firms
compete for influencers considering the overlap and degrees in the influencers’ reach in a social
network. Fainmesser and Galeotti (2021) study a market in which influencers maximize sponsorship
revenues by choosing how much sponsored and organic content to post. Jain and Qian (2021)
analyze how competition among online content producers, the size of the consumer base, and
consumers’ time constraints affect retailers’ revenue-sharing strategies. Pei and Mayzlin (2022)
study the optimal business relationship between a firm and influencers. Janssen and Williams
(2021) study the role of influencers in affecting the order of consumer search. Berman et al. (2023)
investigate how social influencers’ creative contribution to a firm’s marketing campaign affects
the firm’s profit by influencing the dispersion of the market demand for its product. Nistor and
Selove (2022) focus on how an influencer’s entertainment level affects the informativeness of their
comment section and which products they endorse. This literature focuses on influencers who are
paid per content endorsement (akin to how most advertisers are paid). Our main departure from
this literature is that we study a performance-based marketing model, affiliate marketing, in which
influencers are paid per performance (per click and/or per purchase).
There exists some empirical literature on affiliate marketing.
8
Papatla and Bhatnagar (2002)
demonstrates the effect and advantage for an online retailer from having affiliates, even if such
affiliates are also retailers of related products. Olbrich et al. (2019) find how Search Engine Opti-
mization (SEO) can cannibalize the effect of affiliate marketing when merchants run multi-channel
campaigns. Additional work focuses on various practical issues related to affiliate marketing, such
as control mechanisms and contract designs (Gilliland and Rudd 2013), affiliate fraud (Edelman
8
Early case studies include Hoffman and Novak (2000) on one of the earliest and most successful affiliate program,
the BuyWeb Network of CD Now, a music retailer, and how it integrated affiliate marketing into its multifaceted cus-
tomer acquisition strategy, and Duffy (2005), identifying a key to successful affiliate marketing, i.e., the construction
of a win-win relationship between the advertiser and the affiliate.
6
and Brandi 2015), absence of endorsement disclosure (Mathur et al. 2018), deceptive and fabricated
reviews (Karabas et al. 2021), and effects of language features on consumer engagement (Syrdal
et al. 2023).
To our knowledge, there are two papers studying affiliate marketing theoretically. Libai et al.
(2003) consider non-strategic affiliates and compares pay-per-purchase and pay-per-click from a
retailer’s perspective. Suryanarayana et al. (2019) study a model in which affiliates arrive sequen-
tially, and analyze a retailer’s optimal information disclosure to affiliates as they arrive. In this
paper there is only one product and the retailer maximizes the revenue from selling that product.
2 Model
Consider a market with many products, one of which is more salient than the others. Affiliates
(he/they) receive stochastic signals on the qualities of the products and each affiliate chooses
one product to recommend online by providing an affiliate link. A consumer (she) observes the
recommendations of the affiliates and decides whether to click on affiliate links as part of her costly
search for a high quality product. We next describe each of the components of our model: products,
the affiliates’ information sets, the consumer, and the timeline of the model.
2.1 Products
A single retailer (e.g., Amazon) simultaneously offers a unit measure of distinct and substitutable
products online. Ex-ante, products are divided into two types. There is one commonly known
salient product, hereafter product 0.
9
The remaining products are non-salient. The formal differ-
ence between the salient and non-salient products will become clear in Subsection 2.2. We denote
the set of non-salient products by NS.
Products are vertically differentiated. Each product i {0} NS, regardless of its salience,
has ex ante equal probability of being high or low quality, denoted by q
i
{H, L}. That is,
P r(q
i
= H) = P r(q
i
= L) = 1/2. The realizations of products’ qualities are drawn independently.
The prices of the products are all equal and normalized to 1.
9
We leave unmodeled the reasons leading to product 0 being salient, such as brand market share, past marketing
campaigns, or superior brand awareness.
7
2.2 Affiliates’ Information
There are N affiliates, who actively post recommendations for the retailer’s products (each on his
channel, e.g., TikTok, YouTube, or a blog).
10
An affiliate j does not observe the qualities of the
products but receives a signal s
j
(i) {h, l} for each product i from a set η
j
{0}NS that includes
the salient product (product 0) and a countably infinite collection of products chosen uniformly at
random (u.a.r.) from the set of non-salient products, N S.
11
The signal s
j
(i) is generated such that
P r(s
j
(i) = h|q
i
= H) = P r(s
j
(i) = l|q
i
= L) = p
0
> 1/2 for all j = 1, . . . , N and i η
j
. Signals
are conditionally independent across affiliates and products. Taking into account his signals, each
affiliate j recommends a single product online by posting an affiliate link. Such an affiliate link
can direct the consumer to the web page of the recommended product on the retailer’s online
marketplace.
Each affiliate maximizes his monetary compensation, which has two components:
1. Per-click compensation: a commission of λ (0, 1) if the consumer clicks on the link posted
by the affiliate.
2. Per-purchase compensation: a commission of 1 λ if the consumer clicks on the link posted
by the affiliate and buys the recommended product.
That is, an affiliate’s payoff is π
j
=
click
·λ+
purchase
·(1λ) where
click
and
purchase
are the
indicator functions for whether the consumer clicks the affiliate’s link and purchases the product
recommended by the affiliate respectively.
12
2.3 The consumer
There is one consumer with unit demand who is aware of all of the products. The consumer observes
the product recommendations made by the affiliates, and engages in a sequential search: she can
click on a link to a product (either an affiliate link provided by an affiliate, or a link she finds
by searching a product online), evaluate and perfectly observe the product’s quality, and make
10
The set of N affiliates is presumably much smaller than the set of all affiliates active in the market and represents
the affiliates the consumer considers. These affiliates could be the consumer’s selection among the top results from
her search for the products on a search engine.
11
This approximates the case in which each affiliate receives signals for a large number of products, which is
nevertheless small relative to the set of all products.
12
The commission amount in practice is typically a fraction of the price of the product. The retailer only revises
the fraction infrequently, if at all, and hence we keep the fraction given and fixed in the model.
8
a purchasing decision. If the consumer does not purchase the first product she evaluates, with
(exogenous) probability q [0, 1] she can click on a second link to another product and repeat the
process.
13
For simplicity, we assume the consumer never clicks on a third link.
14
We abstract from
product pricing and vertical differentiation and assume that the consumer has a net utility of 1 if
she purchases a high quality product and 1 if she purchases a low quality product.
Evaluating a product’s quality involves reviewing product specifications and reading other con-
sumers’ reviews. We capture the effort invested in learning about the product’s quality by a cost c
the consumer incurs each time she learns about a new product. Therefore, if the consumer searched
n {1, 2} products before finding a high quality product, her payoff is 1 nc. We focus attention
on small enough c so that the consumer finds it profitable (in expectations) to click on a link to a
product she believes to be of high quality with probability p
0
or higher.
15
2.4 Timeline and equilibrium
To sum, the timeline of our model is as follows:
1. Nature determines products qualities.
2. Each affiliate j receives independent signals about the qualities of products in η
j
and chooses
one product to recommend. Affiliates make their recommendations simultaneously.
3. The consumer observes the product recommendations made by the affiliates and searches for
a high quality product as described above.
A strategy for affiliate j is a map {h, l}
η
j
η
j
from quality signals for products in the set
η
j
to a (potentially stochastic) recommendation. A strategy for the consumer is a map ({0}
NS)
{1,2,...,N}
∆(({0} N S ) × ({0} NS )) from the vector of the recommended products
by all of the affiliates to a (potentially stochastic) choice of at most two products, one that she
clicks on first, and another that she clicks on with probability q if she didn’t purchase the product
she clicked on first.
13
There are many potential reasons for the consumer to stop her search: outside distractions, fatigue, or other
time and mental constraints.
14
The possibility of a second click is sufficient to capture the effect of consumer’s search length on affiliates’
recommendation decisions and conformity incentive, while maintaining the tractability of the model.
15
In fact, if c is sufficiently large to deter the consumer from clicking on a link for a product that is of high quality
with probability p
0
, all equilibria of the game are such that no search takes place and no link is ever clicked.
9
A Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium is a collection of affiliates and consumer strategies and beliefs
such that each affiliate’s strategy maximizes his expected profit, the consumer’s strategy maximizes
her expected utility, and all beliefs are consistent with Bayes law whenever possible. In what follows,
whenever we refer to an equilibrium, we mean a Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium.
2.5 Discussion of modeling assumptions
2.5.1 The commission model: pay-per-click vs. pay-per-purchase
As mentioned in the introduction, a minority of retailers and retail platforms still follow the outright
pay-per-click affiliate commission model. However, most, if not all, retailers who follow a pay-per-
purchase affiliate commission model pay an affiliate on any purchase made by consumers within a
relatively large time frame (the “cookie duration”), regardless of whether the consumers purchased
the products recommended by the affiliate. This practice provides affiliates with pay-per-click-like
incentives. That is, an affiliate has at least a component of his expected payoff independent of
whether the product he recommends is purchased.
In our baseline model, we abstract from the specific implementation of the compensation offered
by the retailer and capture the pay-per-click-like component by λ. One can interpret a retailer’s
commission model with a high λ as the retailer offering its affiliates a longer cookie duration,
providing affiliates with greater flexibility of receiving a commission beyond a sale of a linked
product. In Section 4.2, we formulate a model that explicitly captures the pay-per-purchase-with-
time-frame environment and shows how it is nested within our current model. We then apply this
formalization to analyze the retailer’s choice of affiliates’ compensation model.
2.5.2 Single salient product
For tractability, we assume throughout that there is one salient product. While we expect many
of our results to extend to an environment with multiple salient products, such an environment
may also introduce the possibility of additional forms of conformity.
16
We leave the investigation
of other conformity equilibria in a richer model for future research.
16
For example, one strong form of conformity will be one in which affiliates’ establish an ordering of the salient
products, such that all affiliates who receive a high signal for product ‘a’ recommend it, all affiliates who receive a
low signal for product ‘a’ and a high signal for product ‘b’ recommend product ‘b’, and so forth. The sustainability
of some of these conformity strategy profiles in equilibrium might require the model to allow the consumer’s longer
search duration accordingly.
10
2.5.3 Informed consumer
We assume that once the consumer evaluates a product, she will perfectly learn the product’s
quality. We relax this assumption and explore the effect of the consumer’s ability to self-evaluate
products in Section 4.1. We show that our results extend qualitatively to this more general case
and derive new insights from emerging quantitative changes.
3 Results: conflict of interest and affiliates’ conformity
Due to the nature of the coordination game between affiliates and the asymmetric information
between affiliates and the consumer, our model admits a large set of equilibria, including some less
interesting (or realistic) ones in which some (or all) products are never recommended and never
purchased with corresponding ad-hoc beliefs over zero probability events. Therefore, instead of
characterizing the entire set of equilibria, we first show that two affiliates’ strategy profiles stand
out because, for any set of parameters, one of the two strategy profiles always maximizes affiliates’
and/or the consumer’s payoffs. These two strategy profiles are polar opposites, and their optimality
highlights an inherent conflict of interest in this market. Then, we characterize the range of market
parameters for which each of the two strategy profiles is an equilibrium, highlighting important
trade-offs and inefficiencies.
3.1 Conflict of interest
Our first result characterizes the inherent conflict of interest between the affiliates as a group and
the consumer with respect to recommendations of salient versus non-salient products and how it
depends on the length of consumer search and on affiliates’ compensation. Two affiliates’ strategy
profiles emerge as important in our analysis.
Definition 1. A conformity strategy profile is a strategy profile in which every affiliate who receives
a high signal for the salient product recommends it and every affiliate who receives a low signal
for the salient product recommends a non-salient product for which he received a high signal. A
conformity equilibrium is an equilibrium in which affiliates employ a conformity strategy profile.
A non-conformity strategy profile is a strategy profile in which, regardless of their signals for
the salient product, every affiliate recommends a non-salient product for which he received a high
11
signal. A non-conformity equilibrium is an equilibrium in which affiliates employ a non-conformity
strategy profile.
Proposition 1. Suppose the consumer best responds given the affiliates’ strategy profile (and some
beliefs that are consistent with the Bayes’s rule given the affiliates’ strategy profile).
17
Then,
(1) a conformity strategy profile maximizes the consumer’s expected payoff among all affiliates’
strategy profiles;
(2) If λ
1p
0
q
1+qp
0
q
, then a non-conformity strategy profile maximizes the affiliates’ aggregate
expected payoff among all affiliates’ strategy profiles; otherwise, a conformity strategy profile
maximizes the affiliates’ aggregate expected payoff among all affiliates’ strategy profiles.
Proposition 1 delivers a bang-bang result: depending on the parameters of our model, the
affiliates and the consumer may have completely aligned interests or completely opposite interests
(but nothing in between) on whether affiliates recommend the salient product when they receive a
positive signal on its quality.
Part (1) of Proposition 1 shows that regardless of the parameters of the model, the consumer
benefits from affiliates’ conformity. Intuitively, affiliates’ conformity allows the consumer to have
more accurate information on at least one product (the salient product). This increases the proba-
bility that the first product that the consumer clicks on is of high quality, leading to: (1) a shorter
and less costly search, and (2) a higher probability of the search ending with a purchase of a high
quality product.
Note that the condition λ
1p
0
q
1+qp
0
q
in part (2) of Proposition 1 can be equivalently expressed
as p
0
1λλq
qλq
, or q
1λ
λ+p
0
λp
0
. Therefore, affiliates’ total expected payoffs are the highest under
non-conformity, if: (1) a significant fraction of affiliates’ compensation is per-click, (2) the consumer
is likely to continue searching after a click that doesn’t lead to a purchase, and (3) affiliates receive
sufficiently accurate signals on products’ qualities. In this case, the consumer and the affiliates
have opposing interests.
18
17
This is akin to a hypothetical scenario in which affiliates’ strategy profile can be exogenously determined and
publicly announced and the consumer best responds to it.
18
Note also that
1λλq
qλq
> 1 if and only if 1 λ > q, or λ + q < 1. It follows that, if λ + q < 1, then
1λλq
qλq
> p
0
for all p
0
1, that is, the condition in part (2) of Proposition 1 cannot hold. Therefore, if a sufficiently large fraction
of affiliates’ compensation is per-purchase (low λ) or if the consumer’s search is sufficiently short (low q). Affiliates
(as a group) have aligned interests with the consumer regardless of the affiliates’ information accuracy p
0
.
12
Intuitively, when affiliates are compensated significantly per click, and when it is likely that the
consumer will continue clicking after not purchasing, the average expected payoff for an affiliate
increases in the expected length of the consumer’s search. At the same time, as long as affiliates’
compensation does not put significant weight on the purchase, affiliates’ expected payoffs are not
reduced much if the search is likely not to end in a purchase. Conversely, suppose affiliates are
compensated mainly per purchase, and the consumer is expected to stop searching after an unsuc-
cessful first click. In that case, affiliates’ interests align with the consumer’s preference for affiliates’
conformity. Figure 1 captures these observations.
The effect of the accuracy of the affiliates’ signals is more subtle. A high accuracy signal implies
that the search will likely end in purchase even if affiliates do not conform to their recommendations,
thus making the non-conformity outcome better for affiliates. This effect is more substantial when
a larger fraction of affiliates’ compensation is per purchase and the probability that the consumer
continues searching after one low-quality product is high. We can see this effect by comparing the
contour lines in Figure 1.
13
Figure 1: Affiliates’ preference for conformity
For three values of p
0
, the figure illustrates a partition of the q-λ space that distinguishes
when affiliates prefer conformity (vs. non-conformity). Affiliates’ aggregate payoff is
highest under conformity when affiliates are compensated heavily per-purchase (small λ)
and consumer search is short (small q). In contrast, affiliates’ aggregate payoff is highest
under non-conformity when affiliates are compensated heavily per-click (large λ) and
consumer search is long (large q). If affiliates signals are more accurate (large p
0
) the
range of parameters for which affiliates’ aggregate payoff is highest under conformity is
smaller. (In the figure N = 10.)
3.2 Equilibrium and affiliates’ conformity
We now analyze the conditions under which affiliates’ conformity and non-conformity can be sup-
ported as equilibrium outcomes. We first show that regardless of the parameters of the model, there
exists a non-conformity equilibrium, i.e., an equilibrium in which no affiliate ever recommends the
salient product.
Proposition 2. There always exists a non-conformity equilibrium.
Proposition 2 provides bad news for the consumer, whose payoff is maximized under affili-
ates’ conformity. Proposition 2 suggests that affiliates’ non-conformity can emerge in equilibrium
regardless of the parameters of the model. When combined with Proposition 1, Proposition 2 pro-
vides good news to the affiliates when affiliates’ payoffs have a significant per-click component or
consumers are more likely to continue their search beyond the first click.
14
To gain intuition for Proposition 2, it is useful to consider the case that the consumer follows
exactly two affiliates. In this case, essentially all equilibria are non-conformity equilibria.
19
To
gain intuition into why when N = 2 this equilibrium is unique, consider an equilibrium candidate
in which any affiliate who receives a good signal for the salient product recommends the salient
product with some positive probability. Assume by contradiction that this is an equilibrium. Then,
if one affiliate recommends the salient product and one doesn’t, this informs the consumer that one
of them received a good signal for the salient product and the other, at least with some positive
probability, received a negative signal for the salient product. As a result, the consumer’s posterior
puts a higher probability that the recommended non-salient product is of high quality than that
the salient product is high quality. If such an equilibrium exists, the only situation in which the
consumer will click the salient product is if both affiliates recommend the salient product. However,
in that case, each of the affiliates can deviate to recommend a non-salient product and receives the
consumer’s click with probability 1.
When N > 2, additional equilibria may exist. Motivated by Proposition 1, which tells us that a
conformity equilibrium maximizes the consumer’s payoffs and sometimes maximizes also affiliates’
payoffs (and thus aggregate social welfare), our next result characterizes the set of parameters for
which affiliates’ conformity is an equilibrium.
Proposition 3. Fix any N > 2. For any q, λ there exist
1
2
p ¯p < 1 such that:
20
(1) for every p
0
> ¯p, there exists a conformity equilibrium; and
(2) for every p
0
< p, a conformity equilibrium does not exist.
The intuition for Proposition 3 is most straightforward when considering N large yet finite. That
is, the consumer observes the recommendations of a large (finite) number of affiliates: Consider
affiliate j, and suppose that the quality of the salient product is high and all other affiliates act
according to the conformity strategy profile, that is, if they receive a positive signal on the salient
19
There is only one additional equilibrium in which at most one affiliate recommends the salient product. This
equilibrium is equivalent to a non-conformity equilibrium in the sense that no one product is ever recommended by
two affiliates in equilibrium.
20
Moreover, for any 0 λ 1, there exists a unique ˆq (0, 1) such that for any q ̸= ˆq, the upper bound p(q, λ)
for the range of p
0
on the non-existence of a conformity equilibrium is strictly larger than
1
2
. Therefore, generically,
the proposition can be re-written with strict inequalities
1
2
< p ¯p < 1 and we can say that generically for any
0 q 1 and 0 λ 1 there exists ranges of p
0
in which a conformity equilibrium exists and ranges of p
0
in which
a conformity equilibrium does not exist.
15
product they post a recommendation for it. Then, there is a considerable probability that the salient
product gets most of the recommendations observed by the consumer. This probability increases
in the accuracy of the affiliates’ signals, p
0
. As p
0
approaches 1, the probability that conditional on
being high quality, the salient product gets an overwhelming majority of the recommendations is
high. In that case, the consumer clicks first on a link to the salient product with high probability,
and because the salient product is of high quality, the consumer will not search further. Therefore, to
have a chance of having his link clicked on, affiliate j would need to recommend the salient product
when the salient product is of high quality. It is just left to note that, for a high information
accuracy p
0
, the probability that the salient product is of high quality conditional on affiliate j
receiving a positive signal is high.
When considered in tandem with Proposition 1, Proposition 3 carries two main welfare impli-
cations. First, even when both the consumer and the affiliates would benefit from the affiliates’
conformity, a conformity equilibrium may not exist, leading to a sub-optimal equilibrium outcome.
This sub-optimal outcome occurs, for example, when affiliates’ signals are sufficiently inaccurate.
Second, even when affiliates as a group prefer non-conformity, a conformity equilibrium may
exist. For example, part 1 of Proposition 3 tells us that a conformity equilibrium exists if affiliates
receive sufficiently accurate product quality signals. However, Proposition 1 tells us that this is the
case in which the affiliates can maximize their aggregate payoffs when they never recommend the
salient product. Notably, a conformity equilibrium is always ideal for the consumer. We illustrate
these two welfare implications in Figure 2.
16
Figure 2: Conformity-driven inefficiency
Below the dark blue dashed line (regions I, III, and V), affiliates achieve the maximal
aggregate payoff under affiliates’ conformity, whereas above the dashed line (regions II,
IV, and VI), affiliates achieve maximal aggregate payoff under their non-conformity. Be-
tween the two solid lines (regions II and III), a conformity equilibrium exists. In regions
I and IV, a conformity equilibrium does not exist due to affiliates’ too strong incentive to
recommend the salient product even after they learn it is of low quality. In regions V and
VI, a conformity equilibrium does not exist due to too-strong incentives to recommend
the non-salient product. In region I (shaded with solid grey), a conformity equilibrium
does not exist, but both the consumer and the affiliates achieve the maximal payoffs
under affiliates’ conformity. In region II (shaded with dots), a conformity equilibrium
exists, but affiliates can maximize their aggregate payoff from non-conformity. (In the
figure N = 10, p
0
= 0.57.)
We can say more.
Corollary 1. Let ¯p
0
(q, λ) be the lowest signal accuracy above which there always exists a conformity
equilibrium, i.e., ¯p
0
(q, λ) := min{¯p(q, λ)}. Then,
(1) there exist 0 < q q < 1 such that if q < q, then p
0
(q, λ) is decreasing in λ, and if q > q,
then p
0
(q, λ) is increasing in λ;
(2) for any λ, there exist 0 < q q < 1 such that if q < q, then p
0
(q, λ) is decreasing in q, and
if q > q, then p
0
(q, λ) is increasing in q.
Corollary 1 shows that the expected length of the consumer’s search and the affiliates’ com-
17
pensation scheme have non-monotonic effects on the existence of a conformity equilibrium. As
a result, a conformity equilibrium is most likely to exist if the affiliate compensation scheme is
between per-click and per-purchase compensation and when consumers’ search is of intermediate
length. This assertion is interesting because, as mentioned in the introduction, in recent years,
affiliate programs have converged on an affiliate compensation scheme that is effectively between
per-click and per-purchase compensation.
To better understand the source of this non-monotonicity, assume that all affiliates employ
conformity strategies and consider the following two conceivable unilateral deviations: (1) an af-
filiate who receives a high-quality signal for the salient product may, nevertheless, recommend a
non-salient product, and (2) an affiliate who receives a low-quality signal for the salient product
may, despite his signal, recommend the salient product.
Consider part (2) of Corollary 1. An increase in the expected duration q of the consumer’s
search makes deviation (1) more profitable and deviation (2) less profitable. So much so that when
the search duration is short, there is no p
0
for which deviation (1) is viable. Hence, when the search
duration is short, the range of p
0
for which any profitable deviation exists reduces in the search
duration. Once the search duration is sufficiently high, deviation (2) is no longer viable, but for
sufficiently low p
0
, deviation (1) is. In this range of q, the range of p
0
for which any profitable
deviation exists widens in the search duration. This effect is captured by part (2) of Corollary 1
and illustrated in Figure 3.
18
Figure 3: Existence of conformity equilibrium
In region A, a conformity equilibrium exists. In regions B and C a conformity equilibrium
does not exist: in region B this is due to too-strong incentives to recommend the salient
product (even when an affiliate receives a bad signal for it), whereas in region C this
is due to too-strong incentives to recommend the non-salient product. (In the figure
λ = 0.5, N = 10.)
The intuition for part (1) of the corollary follows a similar logic. An increase in the per-
click compensation, λ, make deviation (1) more profitable because it reduces the importance of
recommending a product that will be purchased (recalls that the salient product, if clicked on,
is more likely to be purchased). For the same reason, an increase in λ also makes deviation (2)
less profitable (more generally, it increases the expected profit from recommending a non-salient
product vis-a-vis the salient product). Therefore, as part (1) of the corollary shows, an increase in
λ has the opposite effect on p
0
when the conformity equilibrium is threatened by the possibility of
deviation (1) versus when it is threatened by deviation (2).
4 Discussion: extensions and broader implications
In this section, we first show that our model is robust to the case in which the consumer does not
observe the quality of a product directly after clicking on an affiliate link. We derive implications for
the case of experience goods. We then consider the platform’s problem: optimal design of affiliate
incentives. We show that whether the platform prefers to put heavier weight on per-purchase vs.
19
per-click compensation depends on how good the platform is at converting clicks to purchases and
on the consumer’s expected search duration. We conclude by providing managerial implications.
4.1 Experience goods and the role of affiliates
In our baseline model we assumed that once a consumer clicks on a link to a product, she observes
the product’s quality accurately. As a result, affiliates had the role of influencing the consumer’s
search without having an effect on whether a consumer purchases a product after she viewed
it. While this assumption provides a reasonable approximation for many product markets, some
products require the consumer to purchase before learning the quality accurately. In such cases,
the consumer may take into account the affiliate’s recommendations in her purchase decision even
after viewing the product page.
We now consider a more general model in which the consumer observes some information about
the product in the form of a potentially noisy signal. Formally, suppose that after the consumer
clicks an affiliate link for product i {0} NS, she observes a signal ˜s(i) {
˜
h,
˜
l} such that
P r(˜s(i) =
˜
h|q
i
= H) = P r(˜s(i) =
˜
l|q
i
= L) = π
0
> 1/2. We assume that the consumer’s signal is
conditionally independent from those of the affiliates. The affiliates’ information, the payoffs for
the affiliates and the consumer, and the timing of the game remain the same as in our baseline
model (Section 2).
We find all our results for the baseline model hold.
Proposition 4. In the model in which the consumer observes a signal from clicking on an affiliate’s
link:
(1) (Proposition 1) A conformity strategy profile maximizes the consumer’s expected payoff among
all affiliates’ strategy profiles.
(2) (Proposition 1) If λ >
1p
0
q
1+qp
0
q
, then a non-conformity strategy profile maximizes the affiliates’
aggregate expected payoff among all affiliates’ strategy profiles; otherwise, a conformity strategy
profile maximizes the affiliates’ aggregate expected payoff among all affiliates’ strategy profiles.
(3) (Proposition 2) There always exists a non-conformity equilibrium.
(4) (Proposition 3) Fix any N > 2, there exist
1
2
< p
p
′′
< 1 such that, for all q, λ:
20
(a) for every p
0
> p
′′
, there exists a conformity equilibrium;
(b) for every p
0
< p
, a conformity equilibrium does not exist.
An interesting special case is the case of experience goods—goods on which the consumer obtains
no quality signal before trying out the good.
21
This is captured by the limit case in which the
consumer observes an uninformative signal, i.e., π
0
= 1/2. For this case we can say more.
Corollary 2. In the model of experience goods:
(1) both conformity and non-conformity strategy profiles maximize the affiliates’ aggregate ex-
pected payoff among all strategy profile.
(2) affiliate compensation (λ) and the length of consumer search (q) do not affect the range of
affiliate signal accuracy level (p
0
) for which a conformity equilibrium exists.
An immediate broader implication of this observation is that in markets for experience goods,
the retailer cannot affect equilibrium behavior via affiliate compensation.
The intuition behind Corollary 2 begins by noting that this scenario is mathematically equivalent
to our baseline model when parameters’ values are set to λ = 1 and q = 0. To see why, note that
for every strategy profile pursued by the affiliates, the consumer’s unique best response is to click
on the link to a product that has the highest posterior probability of being high quality and to
purchase that product. That is, any affiliate’s expectation of being clicked on is identical to our
baseline model in which the consumers clicks only once (q = 0). The affiliate then expects to be
paid λ + (1 λ) = 1 if his link is clicked on by the consumer, but the probability of purchase
conditional on clicking is 1, and therefore identical to what he’s paid in our baseline model when
λ = 1.
4.2 Platform’s design
So far we have treated the affiliate compensation scheme as exogenous. In reality, however, every
online retailer has the ability to design the compensation scheme of its affiliate program. In the
early days of e-commerce, formal pay-per-click compensations schemes were common. The rise of
21
Many personal services fall into this category (e.g. restaurant, hairdresser, beauty salon, theme park, travel,
holiday).
21
bots and click-fraud led many retailers to change their compensation model to pay-per-purchase,
in order to guarantee that paid clicks arrive from real consumers.
However, as suggested in Section 2.5.1, a large component of the compensations scheme of many
affiliate programs is still in expectations in the form of pay-per-click compensation. Affiliate pro-
grams achieve that by paying affiliates for any purchase of the consumer within a predetermined
time-frame after the click. The longer the time-frame the larger the expected share of compensation
coming from per-click-like payments (relative to per-purchase). Additional platform design con-
sideration that increase the effective per-click compensation are larger product variety and better
platform internal recommendation system, as they increase the probability that a consumer buys
something on the platform.
We capture the platform’s objective within our model as follows: Let r be the probability that,
conditional on clicking, the consumer buys a different product on the platform, and let v be the
expected sale price of that product. Normalize the sale price of the product recommended by the
affiliate to 1. Finally, let ρ be the commission in terms of the fraction of the sale price paid to the
affiliate.
The expected payoff for the affiliate, conditional on the consumer clicking on his recommenda-
tion, can be written as
ρ · (Pr(consumer buys the affiliate-recommended product conditional on clicking) + r · v).
By varying the time frame for compensation and its recommendation algorithm the platform
changes r (and maybe also v) and thus the relative weights given to pay-per-click vs. pay-per-
purchase in the affiliate’s compensation scheme. We note that this compensation scheme is captured
by our modeling above when ρ is normalized so that ρ + r · v · ρ = 1.
22
We denote by P
c
the probability that the platform sells a product recommended by an affiliate in
a conformity equilibrium and by P
nc
the probability of such a sale in a non-conformity equilibrium.
22
To see how, set λ = r · v · ρ and note that by the normalization 1 λ = ρ. Moreover, because the normalization
does not affect any of our results above, the platform can always change ρ without affecting the equilibrium—the
only restriction is that ρ is sufficiently high so that, in equilibrium, affiliates’ expected incomes are such that they
stay active. Since the platform can modify ρ it will then pay affiliate the lowest total payoff to keep them active and
can adjust the compensation structure to the equilibrium played so that it delivers to affiliates the same minimal
expected payoff. Thus, without loss of generality, we can focus on the platform’s choice of λ (through its choice
of policies affecting r, such as the time frame considered for affiliate compensation), and assume that the platform
chooses ρ to maximize its revenues.
22
We denote by τ the additional expected revenue to the platform from a click directed to it by
an affiliate, and by x
c
and x
nc
the expected number of clicks in a conformity and non-conformity
equilibrium respectively.
Let E {c, nc}. The platform’s revenue is then captured by
π
E
= P
E
+ x
E
· τ (1)
Next, note that our analysis above (Proposition 1) shows that P
c
P
nc
. On the other hand, the
same analysis shows that x
c
x
nc
. Therefore, holding all else equal, a platform that converts a
click into higher revenues (high τ ) will prefer a non-conformity equilibrium, whereas a platform
that does not converts clicks into high revenues will prefer a conformity equilibrium.
In addition, as we showed in Section 4.1, for a platform selling experience goods x
c
= x
nc
, and
such a platform, therefore, will always prefer a conformity equilibrium.
The remaining question is then, how can a platform affect whether a conformity or non-
conformity equilibrium is played. Due to the multiplicity of equilibria the platform may not be
able to deterministically affect which equilibrium is played. However, it can affect whether a con-
formity equilibrium exists or not. Corollary 1 provides guidelines to a platform seeking to affect
the existence of a conformity equilibrium. In particular,
1. If the consumer’s search is expected to be short (low q), the platform can make conformity
equilibrium exist (not exist) by increasing (decreasing) the share of compensation paid per-
click (λ).
2. If the consumer’s search is expected to be long (high q), the platform can make conformity
equilibrium exist (not exist) by decreasing (increasing) the share of compensation paid per-
click (λ).
4.3 Managerial implications
This paper provides managerial implications for affiliates, brands, and platforms alike.
23
Affiliates
If affiliates have accurate signals of products’ qualities, they will benefit the most under a non-
conformity equilibrium, which always exists. Therefore, affiliates can benefit from coordinating
on a non-conformity equilibrium. However, this is the scenario in which a conformity equilibrium
also exists, which makes affiliates’ coordination on a non-conformity strategy profile tricky because
consumers prefer a conformity equilibrium. A well-informed regulator might try to crack down on
such attempts.
In contrast, if affiliates’ signals are less accurate, they will benefit from conformity. Unfortu-
nately, this is the scenario in which a conformity equilibrium may not exist, to the detriment of
the affiliates and the consumers. All parties in this case (except non-salient brands) will benefit
from increasing the availability of accurate information to all affiliates. Improving the accuracy
of affiliates’ product quality information can be done, for example, by a salient brand or platform
providing samples to affiliates (more on that below) or by affiliates investing more intensively in
gathering information.
In markets for experience goods, in which consumers do not receive quality signals indepen-
dent of affiliates’ recommendations, affiliates are indifferent between conformity and non-conformity
equilibria. Because consumers prefer conformity equilibria, if affiliates engage in conformity equi-
librium, more consumers will be attracted to the market, ultimately benefiting all parties.
Brands
When affiliates receive inaccurate signals about product quality, a conformity equilibrium does
not exist. Therefore, the salient brand may want to make accurate quality information readily
accessible as it will make it more likely that a conformity equilibrium exists. Interestingly, this is
consistent with salient brands sending samples to influencers with no conditions on how favorable
their reviews will be.
Platforms
Even while paying per-purchase to avoid click fraud, platforms can balance between per-purchase
compensation and per-click compensation. Shortening the time window for purchase and intro-
ducing a policy that only the latest clicked-on affiliate is compensated for purchases (the “last
24
click wins” model) reduce the “per-click” weight in affiliate compensation. Improvements in the
matching and recommendations algorithms of a platform, increase in the scope of products carried
by a platform, and general price competitiveness and consumer loyalty to the platform increase the
“per-click” weight in the compensation.
Whether the platform prefers a conformity or non-conformity equilibrium depends on the plat-
form’s ability to extract additional unrelated purchases from a click. A platform with a good in-site
recommendation system and a large variety of product categories, such as eBay or Amazon, may
prefer to maximize clicks and, therefore, encourage a non-conformity equilibrium, perhaps by set-
ting the compensation scheme in a way that will not admit a conformity equilibrium. On the other
hand, a platform with a less established recommendation system or a more specialized platform
with a narrow focus is likely to prefer a conformity equilibrium, which increases the probability of
purchase.
If consumers are expected to conduct longer searches, a platform seeking to facilitate a confor-
mity equilibrium will look for a per-purchase compensation scheme. The reverse is true if consumers
conduct shorter searches on average. In contrast, when consumers cannot learn about the prod-
uct quality independently of the affiliates’ recommendations, the platform’s affiliate compensation
scheme does not affect equilibrium behavior and whether salient or non-salient products are sold
in equilibrium.
References
Berman, R., A.
¨
Ory, and X. Zheng (2023). Influence or advertise: The role of social learning in
influencer marketing. Available at SSRN 4324888.
Duffy, D. L. (2005). Affiliate marketing and its impact on e-commerce. Journal of Consumer
MarketingJournal of Consumer Marketing 22 (3), 161–163.
Edelman, B. and W. Brandi (2015). Risk, information, and incentives in online affiliate marketing.
Journal of Marketing Research 52 (1), 1–12.
Fainmesser, I. P. and A. Galeotti (2021). The market for online influence. American Economic
Journal: Microeconomics 13 (4), 332–72.
25
Gilliland, D. I. and J. M. Rudd (2013). Control of electronic channel affiliates: An exploratory
study and research propositions. Journal of Business Research 66 (12), 2650–2656.
Hoffman, D. L. and T. P. Novak (2000). How to acquire customers on the web? Harvard Business
Review 78 (3), 179–188.
Jain, S. and K. Qian (2021). Compensating online content producers: A theoretical analysis.
Management Science 67 (11), 7075–7090.
Janssen, M. and C. Williams (2021). Influencing search. CEPR Discussion Paper 15811.
Jefferson, A. (2016). Networks help drive affiliate marketing into the mainstream: Advertisers
and publishers evolve as the industry shifts. A Forrester Consulting Thought Leadership Paper
Commissioned By Rakuten Affiliate Network.
Karabas, I., I. Kareklas, T. J. Weber, and D. D. Muehling (2021). The impact of review valence and
awareness of deceptive practices on consumers’ responses to online product ratings and reviews.
Journal of Marketing Communications 27 (7), 685–715.
Katona, Z. (2020). Competing for influencers in a social network. NET Institute Working Paper
No. 13-06, Available at SSRN 2335679.
Libai, B., E. Biyalogorsky, and E. Gerstner (2003). Setting referral fees in affiliate marketing.
Journal of Service Research 5 (4), 303–315.
Mathur, A., A. Naryanan, and M. Chetty (2018). Endorsements on social media: An empirical
study of affiliate marketing disclosures on youtube and pinterest. Proceedings of the ACM on
Human-Computer Interaction 2 (CSCW), 1–26.
Moe, W. W. and D. A. Schweidel (2012). Online product opinions: Incidence, evaluation, and
evolution. Marketing Science 31 (3), 372–386.
Moe, W. W. and M. Trusov (2011). The value of social dynamics in online product ratings forums.
Journal of Marketing Research 48 (3), 444–456.
Nistor, C. and M. Selove (2022). Influencers: The power of comments. Available at SSRN 4118010.
26
Olbrich, R., P. M. Bormann, and M. Hundt (2019). Analyzing the click path of affiliate-marketing
campaigns. Journal of Advertising Research 59 (3), 342–356.
Papatla, P. and A. Bhatnagar (2002). Choosing the right mix of on-line affiliates: How do you
select the best? Journal of Advertising 31 (3), 69–81.
Pei, A. and D. Mayzlin (2022). Influencing social media influencers through affiliation. Marketing
Science 41 (3), 593–615.
Shopify (2024). What is affiliate marketing? everything you need to know in 2024. https:
//www.shopify.com/blog/affiliate-marketing. Accessed: 2024-01-22.
Sridhar, S. and R. Srinivasan (2012). Influence effects in online product ratings. Journal of Mar-
keting 76 (5), 70–88.
Suryanarayana, S. A., D. Sarne, and S. Kraus (2019). Information disclosure and partner man-
agement in affiliate marketing. DAI ’19: Proceedings of the First International Conference on
Distributed Artificial Intelligence (3), 1–8.
Syrdal, H. A., S. Myers, S. Sen, P. J. Woodroof, and W. C. McDowell (2023). Influencer marketing
and the growth of affiliates: The effects of language features on engagement behavior. Journal
of Business Research 163, 113875.
Appendix: Proofs of Sections 3 and 4
Proof of Proposition 1. We first use the ex ante homogeneity across the non-salient products to
simplify the consideration of affiliates’ strategy spaces. Because any two non-salient products
are ex ante identical, if an affiliate j receives high signals for two non-salient products, then any
probability distribution of recommendations between the two induces the same outcome. That
is, for any i
1
, i
2
η
j
, with i
1
, i
2
̸= 0 and s
j
(i
1
) = s
j
(i
2
) = h, all of the strategies for affiliate j
holding P r(recommend i
1
) + P r(recommend i
2
) constant induce the same outcome. Therefore, for
the consideration of payoffs, it suffices to pick a representative from each set of strategies with the
same total probability of recommending non-salient products—one that allocates that probability
entirely to one non-salient product. As a result, we are reduced to consider the following set of
27
strategies for each affiliate j: (α
j
, β
j
) [0, 1], where α
j
and β
j
represent the probabilities affiliate j
will recommend product 0 contingent on his signal about it. That is, with probability α
j
, affiliate j
will recommend product 0 after a high signal about product 0, and with probability (1α
j
), he will
recommend a non-salient product for which he receives a high signal; with probability β
j
, affiliate
j will recommend product 0 after a low signal about product 0, and with probability (1 β
j
), he
will recommend a non-salient product for which he receives a high signal.
Denote by P r
H|0
(n)
the consumer’s posterior belief of product 0 being of high quality
when she sees n recommendations for product 0. Being a risk-neutral expected utility maxi-
mizer, the consumer’s best response in her search to a strategy profile for the affiliates is: (1) when
P r
H|0
(n)
p
0
, search product 0 first, if it is of high quality, stop the search and make a purchase
of one unit of product 0, otherwise (with probability q) search a non-salient product among the
recommended ones; when P r
H|0
(n)
< p
0
, search any non-salient product that is recommended
first, if it is of high quality, stop and make a purchase of the searched product, otherwise, (with
probability) search another recommended non-salient product. Therefore, the consumer’s expected
utility is
E[U(q)|n] =
(1 c)p
0
+ (1 2c)(1 p
0
)p
0
q if P r
H|0
(n)
< p
0
(1 c)P r
H|0
(n)
+ (1 2c)
1 P r
H|0
(n)

p
0
q otherwise
(2)
Collecting P r
H|0
(n)
in the later case, we have
(1 c)P r
H|0
(n)
+ (1 2c)
1 P r
H|0
(n)

p
0
q = [1 p
0
q c(1 2p
0
q)]P r
H|0
(n)
+ (1 2c)p
0
q.
The expression above is linear in P r
H|0
(n)
, whose coefficient 1 p
0
q c(1 2p
0
q) must be
positive. This is because when 1 2p
0
q < 0, then clearly it is positive; and when 1 2p
0
q > 0,
1 p
0
q > 1 2p
0
q > c(1 2p
0
q), so it is positive as well. Therefore, consumer’s expected utility is
bounded from below by that when she only considers non-salient products and attains its maximum
when her posterior about product 0 is at the highest, conditional on the number of recommendations
for product 0 is high enough for her to consider product 0 first.
To prove part (1) of the proposition, it is sufficient to show that the conformity strategy profile
maximizes the consumer’s posterior belief about product 0’s quality conditional on the number of
28
recommendations it receives.
Suppose that the affiliates have chosen the strategy profile represented by {(α
j
, β
j
)}
j=1,...,N
.
Let n N be the number of recommendations for product 0 the consumer observes. To streamline
notations, we define the following partitions on the set of affiliates. Let H(n) (L(n), resp.) be the
set of affiliates who receive high signals (low signals, resp.) about product 0, such that |H(n)| =
N
1
N and |L(n)| = N N
1
. Furthermore, let H
0
(n) H(n) (L
0
(n) L(n), resp.) denote the
set of affiliates who choose to recommend product 0. Then by definition, |H
0
(n)| + |L
0
(n)| = n.
First, the probability that product 0 receives n recommendations conditional on that N
1
affili-
ates received high signals about it is
P r
0
(n)
|(h
N
1
, l
NN
1
)
=
n
X
m=1
N
1
m

N N
1
n m
Y
jH
0
(n)
|H
0
(n)|=m
α
j
Y
g H(n)\H
0
(n)
(1α
g
)
Y
kL
0
(n)
β
k
Y
lL(n)\L
0
(n)
(1β
l
).
(3)
Next, as the number N
1
of high signals for product 0 ranges from n to N, the probability that
product 0 will receive n recommendations conditional on its true quality is
P r
0
(n)
|H
=
N
X
N
1
=n
P r
(h
N
1
, l
NN
1
)|H
P r
0
(n)
|(h
N
1
, l
NN
1
)
, (4)
P r
0
(n)
|L
=
N
X
N
1
=n
P r
(h
N
1
, l
NN
1
)|L
P r
0
(n)
|(h
N
1
, l
NN
1
)
. (5)
where the probabilities that product 0 receives N
1
high signals and N N
1
low signals conditional
on its true quality are
P r
(h
N
1
, l
NN
1
)|H
=
N
N
1
p
N
1
0
(1 p
0
)
NN
1
, (6)
P r
(h
N
1
, l
NN
1
)|L
=
N
N
1
(1 p
0
)
N
1
p
NN
1
0
. (7)
Given that the prior quality for product 0 being high or low is equally likely, by Bayes’s Rule, the
consumer’s posterior belief that product 0 is of high quality is
P r
H|0
(n)
=
P r
0
(n)
|H
P r
0
(n)
|H
+ P r
0
(n)
|L
. (8)
By eqs. (6) and (7), the distribution of signals about product 0 received by the affiliates is
29
independent of the affiliates’ strategies, and hence, we are reduced to maximize the conditional
probabilities P r
0
(n)
|(h
N
1
, l
NN
1
)
given by eq. (3). By the symmetry between the α
j
’s and β
j
’s,
and because p
0
> 1/2, it is without loss of generality to assume α
j
β
j
for j = 1, . . . , N. Note
that when 0 β
j
α
j
1, the expression
Y
jH
0
(n)
|H
0
(n)|=m
α
j
Y
gH(n)\H
0
(n)
(1 α
g
)
Y
kL
0
(n)
β
k
Y
lL(n)\L
0
(n)
(1 β
l
) 1,
and it attains maximum value of 1 when either
(1) (α
j
, β
j
) = (1, 1) for j = 1, . . . , N, requiring H
0
(n) = H(n) and L
0
(n) = L(n); or
(2) (α
j
, β
j
) = (1, 0) for j = 1, . . . , N.
However, the first situation above is only possible when N
1
= N, i.e., the entire group of affiliates
all receive high signals about product 0. It is hence non-generic. When (α
j
, β
j
) = (1, 0) for
j = 1, . . . , N, necessarily, m = n = N
1
, implying that the number of recommendations for product
0 that the consumer sees coincides with the number of affiliates who received high signals about
product 0. Therefore, we have shown the strategy profile specified as (α
j
, β
j
) = (1, 0) for j =
1, . . . , N maximizes the consumer’s expected utility from best responding to this strategy profile.
This completes the proof of part (1).
To prove part (2), suppose that the affiliates act according to a strategy profile characterized
by {(α
j
, β
j
)} for j = 1, . . . , N, yielding n recommendations for product 0. Then the affiliates’ total
expected payoff is
EU(α, β) = λ
h
1 + q
1 max
n
p
0
, P r
H|0
(n)
oi
+ (1 λ)
h
max
n
p
0
, P r
H|0
(n)
o
+ p
0
q
1 max
n
p
0
, P r
H|0
(n)
oi
. (9)
Collecting max
p
0
, P r
H|0
(n)

, we can express eq. (9) as
EU(α, β) = [1 p
0
q (1 + q p
0
q)λ] · max
n
p
0
, P r
H|0
(n)
o
+ p
0
q + (1 + q p
0
q)λ. (10)
Note that the affiliates’ total expected payoff is linear in max
p
0
, P r
H|0
(n)

. Therefore, EU(α, β)
attains its maximum when max
p
0
, P r
H|0
(n)

= p
0
if 1 p
0
q (1 + q p
0
q)λ < 0, and when
30
max
p
0
, P r
H|0
(n)

= P r
H|0
(n)
is at its highest if 1 p
0
q (1 + q p
0
q)λ 0. The sign
of the expression 1 p
0
q (1 + q p
0
q)λ induces the affiliates’ preference dichotomy. When
1 p
0
q (1 + q p
0
q)λ 0, the affiliates want to maximize the probability that P r
H|0
(n)
p
0
across all possible realized recommendation profiles, which will be fulfilled by a non-conformity
profile. To the contrary, when 1 p
0
q (1 + q p
0
q)λ 0, the affiliates want to maximize the
probability that P r
H|0
(n)
p
0
, which will be achieved by a conformity profile. This completes
the proof of part (2).
Proof of Proposition 2. Consider the following strategies: all affiliates recommend non-salient prod-
ucts regardless of their signals for product 0. The consumer follows only recommendations for no-
salient products. It is immediate that the affiliates’ strategies are best responses to the consumer’s
strategy. Given that the probability that an affiliate recommends the salient product is zero, the
consumer’s strategy can be supported as best response to the affiliates’ strategies with the following
beliefs: if an affiliate recommends product zero it is a mistake, which is equally likely when the
affiliate receives a high or low signal for the salient product.
Proof of Proposition 3. (1) We verify that a conformity strategy profile constitutes a pure-strategy
equilibrium in the extreme scenario when p
0
= 1 by checking the non-profitability for any affiliate
from a unilateral deviation. Then part (1) of Proposition 3 follows by the continuity of an affiliate
j’s expected payoff in p
0
.
Case 1. Affiliate j observes a high signal s
j
(0) = h for product 0.
When p
0
= 1, P r
(h
k
, l
N1k
)|s
j
(0) = h
= 1 if k = N 1 and 0 otherwise. That is, when
the signal about product quality is perfectly informative, one affiliate’s high signal about product
0 implies all the other affiliates also received high signal about product 0. When all other affiliates
use a conformity strategy, they will all elect to recommend product 0. Then,
E[U
j
(0|s
j
(0) = h), p
0
= 1] =
1
N
> E[U
j
(j|s
j
(0) = h, s
j
(i) = h), p
0
= 1] = 0. (11)
Case 2. When affiliate j observes a low signal s
j
(0) = l. When p
0
= 1, recommending product
0 yields affiliate j a lower expected payoff than recommending a non-salient product i:
E[U
j
(0|s
j
(0) = l, p
0
= 1)] = 0 < E[U
j
(j|s
j
(0) = l, s
j
(i) = h, p
0
= 1)] =
1
N
. (12)
31
Note that affiliate j’s expected utilities following any strategy when all the other affiliates use
the strategy (α
l
, β
l
) = (1, 0) for any l ̸= j are continuous in p
0
for
1
2
< p
0
1. Then, there exists
some
1
2
¯p(q, λ) < 1 such that affiliate j finds no profitable deviation from (α
j
, β
j
) = (1, 0) when
¯p(q, λ) < p
0
1. This completes the proof of part (1).
(2) We show that ¯p
0
(q, λ) >
1
2
except at one point. We consider the limits of affiliate j’s
expected utilities as p
0
approaches
1
2
. When p
0
>
1
2
, product 0 needs
N
2
recommendations for the
consumer to consider first when N is even, and
N+1
2
recommendations when N is odd.
Since affiliate j’s expected utility from recommending a non-salient product is strictly increasing
in q for any
1
2
< p
0
< 1 when s
j
(0) = h, there exists ˆq such that
lim
p
0
(
1
2
)
+
E[U
j
(0|s
j
(0) = h)|q > ˆq] < lim
p
0
(
1
2
)
+
E[U
j
(j|s
j
(0) = h, s
j
(i) = h)|q > ˆq], (13)
lim
p
0
(
1
2
)
+
E[U
j
(0|s
j
(0) = l)|q < ˆq] > lim
p
0
(
1
2
)
+
E[U
j
(j|s
j
(0) = l, s
j
(i) = h)|q < ˆq]. (14)
The reason that the same ˆq can serve as the cutoff for both inequalities (13) and (14) is that as
p
0
1
2
+
, affiliate j’s expected utility is independent from his signal about product 0. Therefore,
when the probability of a second click by the consumer becomes sufficiently high, and when the
signal informativeness becomes sufficiently low, and when all the other affiliates follow the strategy
(α
k
, β
k
) = (1, 0), affiliate j finds it more profitable to recommend a non-salient product than product
0 after receiving a high signal about product 0. Therefore, for any given q (keeping λ and N fixed
throughout) and any p
0
, either q > ˆq or q ˆq must hold. Then affiliate j finds either recommending
product 0 more profitable regardless of his signal about product 0 or recommending a non-salient
product more profitable regardless of his signal about product 0. Therefore, (α, β) = (1, 0) cannot
be an equilibrium profile as p
0
1
2
+
. This proves that ¯p
0
(q, λ) >
1
2
unless q = ˆq. It also follows
that for any q ̸= ˆq, there exists an interval [
1
2
, p
0
(q, λ)] over which the profile (α, β) = (1, 0) does
not constitute an equilibrium. This completes the proof of part (2).
Proof of Corollary 1. (1) By the proof of Proposition 3, part (1), for any λ, as p
0
1
2
+
, it
is strictly more profitable for an affiliate to recommend product 0 when q = 0, and strictly more
profitable to recommend a non-salient product when q = 1. By the compactness of the unit interval
[0, 1], the function λ 7→ ˆq(λ) is strictly bounded between 0 and 1. That is, there exist q and ¯q with
0 < q ¯q < 1 so that q ˆq(λ) ¯q for any λ [0, 1].
32
When q < q, ¯p
0
(q, λ) is determined by the indifference for an affiliate between recommending
any non-salient product for which he received a high signal and product 0 when he received a low
signal for it, whereas it is always more profitable to recommend product 0 after receiving a high
signal for it for any p
0
>
1
2
. As λ increases, say, from λ
1
to λ
1
+ ϵ, recommending a non-salient
product becomes more profitable: for any sufficiently small ϵ > 0,
E[U
j
(i|s
j
(0) = l, s
j
(i) = h, p
0
= ¯p
0
(q, λ
1
), λ = λ
1
+ ϵ)]
> E[U
j
(0|s
j
(0) = l, s
j
(i) = h, p
0
= ¯p
0
(q, λ
1
), λ = λ
1
+ ϵ)].
It follows that ¯p
0
(q, λ
1
+ ϵ) < ¯p
0
(q, λ
1
).
When q > ¯q, ¯p
0
(q, λ) is determined by the indifference for an affiliate between recommending
any non-salient product for which he received a high signal and product 0 when he received a high
signal for it, whereas it is always more profitable to recommend a non-salient after receiving a high
signal for it for any p
0
>
1
2
. As λ increases, say, from λ
1
to λ
1
+ ϵ, recommending a non-salient
product becomes more profitable: for any sufficiently small ϵ > 0,
E[U
j
(j|s
j
(0) = h, s
j
(i) = h, p
0
= ¯p
0
(q, λ
1
), λ = λ
1
+ ϵ)]
> E[U
j
(0|s
j
(0) = h, s
j
(i) = h, p
0
= ¯p
0
(q, λ
1
), λ = λ
1
+ ϵ)].
It follows that ¯p
0
(q, λ
1
+ ϵ) > ¯p
0
(q, λ
1
).
(2) The existence of q(λ) and ¯q(λ) follows from the same compactness argument as in the
proof of part (1). The expected utility from recommending a non-salient product is increasing
with q, whereas the expected utility from recommending the salient product remains constant as q
increases. When q < q(λ) and p
0
= ¯p
0
(q, λ), making a recommendation after receiving a low signal
about the salient product is the binding condition for an affiliate. Then, ¯p
0
(q, λ) > ¯p
0
(q + ϵ, λ)
for any sufficiently small ϵ > 0. When q > ¯q(λ), making a recommendation after receiving a high
signal about the salient product is binding for an affiliate at p
0
= ¯p
0
(q, λ). Again, increasing q will
only increase the expected utility for an affiliate from recommending a non-salient product. So as
q increases to q + ϵ for some sufficiently small ϵ > 0, ¯p
0
(q, λ) is weakly increasing.
Proof of Proposition 4. (1) Let n
0
and n
1
be the unique numbers of recommendations the salient
33
product receives in a recommendation profile so that
n
0
:=
n
1 n N|P r(H|0
(n)
) > p
0
P r(H|
˜
l, 0
(n)
)
o
n
1
:= min
1nN
n
P r(H|
˜
l, 0
(n)
) > p
0
o
That is, n
0
is the threshold number of recommendations that will incentivize the consumer to first
consider the salient product but will only purchase it when her signal is high, and n
1
is the threshold
number of recommendations so that the consumer will purchase the salient product regardless of
her signal. By definition, n
0
< n
1
. Depending on the number of recommendations for the salient
product the consumer sees, we consider the following three cases regarding the consumer’s best
response.
Case 1. n n
1
. This case leads the consumer to purchase the salient product regardless of her
signal about it. The consumer’s expected payoff is
(1 c)P r(H|0
(n)
). (15)
Case 2. n
0
n < n
1
. The consumer will first consider the salient product. She will purchase
a salient product only when her signal about it is high. Otherwise, she will continue to consider a
non-salient product. The consumer’s expected payoff is
(1 c)P r(
˜
h|0
(n)
) · P r(H|
˜
h, 0
(n)
) + q(1 2c)
1 P r(
˜
h|0
(n)
) · P r(H|
˜
h, 0
(n)
)
· P r(
˜
h|h) · P r(H|
˜
h, h).
= (1 c)π
0
· P r
H|0
(n)
+ q(1 2c)π
0
p
0
1 π
0
· P r
H|0
(n)

= [1 p
0
q c(1 2p
0
q)]π
0
P r
H|0
(n)
+ q(1 2c)p
0
π
0
.
Case 3. n < n
0
. In this case, the consumer will only consider non-salient products. She will
only purchase it after seeing a high signal about the focal non-salient product. This is because
when she sees a low signal about it, her posterior belief about the salient product is higher than
that about the non-salient product under her consideration. After the consumer clicks on a link
to a recommended non-salient product i, her belief about the clicked non-salient product’s quality
is updated as P r(H|
˜
h, h) =
p
0
π
0
p
0
π
0
+(1p
0
)(1π
0
)
or P r(H|
˜
l, h) =
p
0
(1π
0
)
p
0
(1π
0
)+(1p
0
)π
0
. The consumer’s
34
expected payoff is:
(1 c) · P r(
˜
h|h) · P r(H|
˜
h, h) + q · (1 2c) · (1 P r(
˜
h|h) · P r(H|
˜
h, h)) · P r(
˜
h|h) · P r(H|
˜
h, h),
= (1 c)p
0
π
0
+ q(1 2c)p
0
π
0
(1 p
0
π
0
). (16)
The equality in (16) follows because
P r(
˜
h|h) = P r(H|h)P r(
˜
h|H) + P r(L|h)P r(
˜
h|L) = p
0
π
0
+ (1 p
0
)(1 π
0
). (17)
Similar to the baseline model, the consumer’s expected payoff attains maximum when her pos-
terior belief about the salient product is the most accurate, which must be induced by a conformity
profile.
(2) Denote by p
+
0
:= P r(H|
˜
h, h) and p
+
n
:= P r(H|
˜
h, 0
(n)
) the consumer’s posterior belief about
a recommended non-salient product and the salient product after she clicks on a link and receives
a high signal, where n is the number of recommendations she sees about product 0.
When n n
1
, the consumer will purchase the salient product after one click. The affiliates’
aggregate expected payoff is
λ + (1 λ) · P r
H|0
(n)
. (18)
When n < n
1
, the affiliates’ aggregate expected payoff is
λ
1 + q(1 max{p
+
n
, p
+
0
})
+ (1 λ)
max{p
+
n
, p
+
0
} + p
0
q(1 max{p
+
n
, p
+
0
})
. (19)
Comparing (18) and (19), we find that a conformity profile maximizes the affiliates’ aggregate
payoff if and only if either
(1) 1 p
0
q (1 + q p
0
q)λ > 0; or
(2) P r
H|0
(n)
>
λ
1λ
q(1 p
0
) + p
0
+ p
0
q(1 p
0
).
The first scenario is identical to the baseline model, yielding a lower bound on p
0
: p
0
<
1λqλ
q(1λ)
.
The second scenario leads to an upper bound on p
0
. Note that the condition in the second scenario
35
is not vacuous if and only if
λ
1λ
q(1 p
0
) + p
0
+ p
0
q(1 p
0
) < 1, which gives rise to
λ <
1 p
0
q
1 + q p
0
q
. (20)
Note that the condition above is the identical condition for scenario 1. Therefore, we identify
the same condition that distinguishes the affiliates’ aggregate preference for conformity as in the
baseline model. In addition, within the case when the affiliates’ aggregate payoff is maximized
under conformity, we identify a further reason for their preference for conformity, which is when
the consumer’s posterior belief about product 0 is sufficiently high, the incentive for the affiliates
to induce the consumer to purchase product 0 after one click leads to the greatest aggregate payoff
for the affiliates.
For parts (3) and (4), the proofs in the baseline model on the existence of a non-conformity
equilibrium and conditions for the existence of a conformity equilibrium still work. The reason
is that, for checking the profitability of unilateral deviations, we only need to compare affiliates’
aggregate payoffs for special sets of parameter values (e.g., p
0
= 1 in the case to characterize the
condition for the existence of a conformity equilibrium). And those comparisons would not change
under the current more general setting.
Proof of Corollary 2. (1) In the model of experience goods, for every strategy profile for the affili-
ates, the consumer’s best response is to click on a link to a product that has the highest posterior
probability of being high quality and to purchase that product. (Because the consumer’s posterior
beliefs are identical for all of the recommended non-salient products, it is therefore unique up to
identification of non-salient products that are recommended.) Therefore, the consumer’s expected
search length is 1, reducing q = 0. Also, the affiliates expect to be paid without distinguishing
being clicked only or inducing a purchase. The affiliates’ aggregate payoff is identical to the special
case of the baseline model with λ = 1.
Therefore, to analyze the model of experience goods, it suffices to look at the special case with
q = 0 and λ = 1. In this scenario, the condition identified in Proposition 1 becomes vacuous,
yielding affiliates as a group indifferent between a conformity profile and non-conformity profile.
(2) Part (2) follows immediately as we have shown in part (1) the equivalence of the model of
experience goods with the special model with q = 0 and λ = 1.
36
Online appendix I: Preliminary analysis
In this section we cover a few observations that highlight the inner workings of the model. First,
because each affiliate observes only a small fraction of all products, the probability that any two
affiliates observe (and recommend) the same non-salient product is 0 and the only product that
has positive probability of receiving multiple recommendations is the salient product (product 0).
Therefore, affiliates’ recommendations segment products into three categories:
23
(1) the salient
product—a recognisable product that can possibly receive more than one recommendation; (2)
non-salient products recommended by one affiliate; and (3) the remaining non-recommended non-
salient products.
Second, because only a fraction of all products is observed by any affiliate, if a non-salient
product does not receive a recommendation, the consumer assigns probability 1 for the product not
being observed by any affiliate. As a result, the posterior belief of the consumer is that a non-salient
product that is not recommended (category 3) is a high quality product is probability 1/2. Note
that because all affiliates observe the salient product, the same is not true for an unrecommended
salient product.
Third, for any λ < 1, an affiliate’s expected payoffs increase in the probability that, conditional
on clicking on the product he recommends, the consumer purchases the product. Because the con-
sumer is able to evaluate the product before purchasing, the probability that a consumer purchases
the product following a click is increasing in the quality of the product. As a result, as long as an
affiliate receives a high signal for at least one non-salient product (which happens with probability
1), it is a weakly dominated strategy for him to recommend a non-salient product for which he
received a low signal. For the same reason, in any equilibrium with weakly undominated strategies
the posterior belief of the consumer is that a non-salient product that is recommended (category
2) is of high quality with probability p
0
.
Fourth, the only undominated strategy for the consumer is to click on links to products in
the order of their posterior probabilities to be of high quality (as long as the expected utility
is higher than c), and buy a product she clicked on immediately if it is revealed to be of high
quality. Moreover, for any c > 0 the consumer will never click on a link to a product that is not
23
We abstract from the zero probability event in which a non-salient product receives more than one recommen-
dation. Accommodating that possibility adds some special cases (all zero probability) to the analysis but doesn’t
introduce any new insights.
37
recommended by any affiliate.
Online appendix II: Further characterizations of equilibria
First, it is straightforward to verify that non-conformity always leads to an equilibrium.
Proposition OA.1. There always exists a pure-strategy equilibrium in which none of the affiliates
ever recommend the salient product regardless of their signals about it and the consumer proceeds
by only searching among non-salient products that are recommended.
Next, let N > 2 be the number of affiliates whose recommendations the consumer will observe.
For any q [0, 1] and λ [0, 1], let p
0
(q, λ) be identified by Proposition 3. That is, p
0
(q, λ) is the
smallest value so that the strategy profile with affiliates recommending according to (α, β) = (1, 0)
and the consumer searching in a posterior-belief-descending order can be sustained for any p
0
(p
0
(q, λ), 1].
Proposition OA.2.
(1) For any p
0
> p
0
(q, λ), the following profile is supported as a mixed-strategy equilibrium: the
affiliates play according to (α(p
0
), 0) for some uniquely determined α(p
0
) (0, 1), and the
consumer proceeds her search in a posterior-belief-descending order.
(2) For any p
0
> p
0
(q, λ), the following profile is supported as a mixed-strategy equilibrium: the
affiliates play according to (1, β(p
0
)) for some uniquely determined β(p
0
) (0, 1), and the
consumer proceeds her search in a posterior-belief-descending order.
Proof. (1) We first consider possible mix-strategy equilibria of the form (α, 0) with 0 < α < 1—
every affiliate recommends the salient product with probability α after receiving a high signal about
it and recommends a non-salient product after receiving a low signal about product 0, and the
consumer proceeds with her search in a posterior-belief-decreasing order (among the recommended
non-salient products, since the consumer’s posterior belief about them are equal, when she decides
to consider non-salient products, she will randomly pick one with equal probability).
Suppose that affiliate i receives a high signal about product 0: s
i
(0) = h. His estimate of the
probability that among the other N 1 affiliates s of them also receive high signals about product
38
0 is
P r
(h
s
, l
N1s
)|s
i
(0) = h
=
N 1
s
h
p
s+1
0
(1 p
0
)
N1s
+ (1 p
0
)
s+1
p
N1k
0
i
. (21)
Hence, after a high signal about product 0, affiliate i’s expectation that product 0 will receive k
recommendations from other affiliates is
E
h
h
0
(k)
i
=
N1
X
s=k
s
k
P r
(h
s
, l
N1s
)|s
i
(0) = h
α
k
(1 α)
sk
. (22)
For consumer’s posterior belief about product 0, conditional on product 0 having high quality,
the probability that the consumer will see k recommendations of product 0 is
P r
0
(k)
|H
= α
k
"
Nk
X
i=0
N
N i

N i
k
p
k+i
0
(1 p
0
)
Nki
(1 α)
i
#
. (23)
We can also derive the probability P r(0
(k)
|L) that the consumer will see k recommendations of
product 0 conditional on product 0 having low quality. Then the consumer’s posterior about
product 0 after seeing k recommendations is
P r
H|0
(k)
=
P r
0
(k)
|H
P r
0
(k)
|H
+ P r
0
(k)
|L
=
P
Nk
i=0
N
Ni

Ni
k
p
k+i
0
(1 p
0
)
Nki
(1 α)
i
P
Nk
i=0
N
Ni

Ni
k
[p
k+i
0
(1 p
0
)
Nki
+ (1 p
0
)
k+i
p
Nki
0
](1 α)
i
. (24)
Similar to the pure-strategy case where (α, β) = (1, 0), we can find a unique k
0
(α) such that product
0 needs to receive at least k
0
(α) recommendations for the consumer to consider first. Since the
consumer’s search lasts at most two steps, she will not consider product 0 when more than one
non-salient products receive recommendations and she did not start the search with product 0.
In the proposed mixed-strategy equilibrium with 0 < α < 1, after seeing a high signal about
product 0, affiliate i must be indifferent between recommending product 0 and non-salient product
39
j for which he receives a high signal. The indifference condition is
E[U
i
(0|s
i
(0) = h, p
0
, α)] = E[U
i
(j|s
i
(0) = h, s
i
(j) = h, p
0
, α)] (25)
N1
X
k=k
0
(α)1
λ + (1 λ)P r
H|0
(k+1)
k + 1
E
h
h
0
(k)
i
=
k
0
(α)2
X
k=0
Γ(λ, q)E
h
h
0
(k)
i
(26)
where as before
Γ(λ, q) = λ
1
N k
+
(1 p
0
)q
N k 1
+ (1 λ)
p
0
N k
+
(1 p
0
)p
0
q
N k 1
. (27)
To confirm the existence of a mixed-strategy equilibrium of the form (α, 0), it suffices to show that
Eq. (26) has a solution in α (0, 1) for any given set of parameters λ, q and N, and when p
0
is
sufficiently high.
When p
0
> ˆp
0
(q, λ) and when all other affiliates deploy the strategy (α, β) = (1, 0), it is
strictly more profitable for affiliate i to also play according to (α, β) = (1, 0), based on the previous
analysis on the pure-strategy equilibrium (α, β) = (1, 0). Similarly, when p
0
> ˆp
0
(q, λ) and when
all other affiliates deploy the strategy (α, β) = (0, 0), it is strictly more profitable for affiliate i to
also play according to (α, β) = (0, 0) from the previous analysis on the pure-strategy equilibrium
(α, β) = (0, 0). Therefore, there exists some α(p
0
, q, λ) (0, 1) that equalizes an affiliate’s expected
utility from recommending product 0 and a non-salient product after receiving high signals about
both when all the other affiliates play according to the mixed strategy (α(p
0
, q, λ), 0).
Lastly, when affiliate i receives a low signal about product 0, and when all the other affiliates
play according to the mixed strategy (α(p
0
, q, λ), 0), it is strictly more profitable for affiliate i to
recommend a non-salient product at α = α(p
0
, q, λ) when p
0
> ˆp
0
(q, λ). Therefore, the mixed-
strategy profile of the form (α(p
0
, q, λ), 0) gives rise to an equilibrium when the consumer searches
in a posterior-belief-descending order.
(2) Consider the mix-strategy profile of the form (1, β) with 0 < β < 1. Note that after a high
signal about product 0, affiliate i’s expectation that product 0 will receive k recommendations from
other affiliates is
E
h
h
0
(k)
i
=
k
X
s=0
N 1 s
k s
P r
(h
s
, l
N1s
)|s
i
(0) = h
β
ks
(1 β)
N1k
. (28)
40
Conditional on product 0 having high quality, the probability that the consumer will see k recom-
mendations of product 0 is
P r
0
(k)
|H
= (1 β)
Nk
"
k
X
i=0
N
i

N i
k i
p
i
0
(1 p
0
)
Ni
β
ki
#
. (29)
We can similarly derive the probability P r
0
(k)
|L
that the consumer will see k recommendations
of product 0 conditional on product 0 having low quality. Then the consumer’s posterior about
product 0 after seeing k recommendations is
P r
H|0
(k)
=
P r
0
(k)
|H
P r
0
(k)
|H
+ P r
0
(k)
|L
=
P
k
i=0
N
i

Ni
ki
p
i
0
(1 p
0
)
Ni
β
ki
P
k
i=0
N
i

Ni
ki
[p
i
0
(1 p
0
)
Ni
+ (1 p
0
)
i
p
Ni
0
]β
ki
. (30)
We can find unique k
0
(β) < k
0
(β) such that product 0 needs to receive at least k
0
(β) and at most
k
0
(β) recommendations for the consumer to consider first.
After seeing a low signal about product 0, affiliate i is necessarily indifferent between recom-
mending product 0 and a non-salient product j for which he receives a high signal. The indifference
condition is
E[U
i
(0|s
i
(0) = l, p
0
, β)] = E[U
i
(j|s
i
(0) = l, s
i
(j) = h, p
0
, β)] (31)
k
0
(β)1
X
k=k
0
(β)1
λ + (1 λ)P r
H|0
(k+1)
k + 1
E
h
h
0
(k)
i
=
X
k<k
0
(β)1 or kk
0
(β)
Γ(λ, q)E
h
h
0
(k)
i
(32)
where as before
Γ(λ, q) = λ
1
N k
+
(1 p
0
)q
N k 1
+ (1 λ)
p
0
N k
+
(1 p
0
)p
0
q
N k 1
. (33)
To confirm the existence of a mixed-strategy equilibrium of the form (1, β), it suffices to show that
Eq. (32) has a solution in β (0, 1) for any given set of parameters λ and q, and when p
0
is
sufficiently high.
When all the other affiliates play according to the strategy (α, β) = (1, 1), when p
0
is sufficiently
high, it is strictly more profitable for affiliate i to also play according to (α, β) = (1, 1). Then
41
there exists some β(p
0
, q, λ) (0, 1) that equalizes affiliate i’s expected utility from recommending
product 0 after a low signal about it and a non-salient product for which he receives a high signal,
when all other affiliates also play according to (α, β) = (1, β(p
0
, q, λ)):
E[U
i
(0|s
i
(0) = l, β = β(p
0
, q, λ))] = E[U
i
(j|s
i
(0) = l, s
i
(j) = h, β = β(p
0
, q, λ))]. (34)
This also shows that when affiliate i receives a high signal about product 0, it is strictly more
profitable for him to recommend product 0. This completes the proof of the existence of a mixed-
strategy equilibrium in which affiliates play according to (α, β) = (1, β(p
0
, q, λ)) and the consumer
searches in a posterior-belief-descending order.
42