JOURNAL OF APPLIED ECONOMETRICS
J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
Published online 22 April 2009 in Wiley InterScience
(www.interscience.wiley.com) DOI: 10.1002/jae.1079
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS?
ANDREW MOUNTFORD
a
* AND HARALD UHLIG
b
a
Royal Holloway, University of London, UK
b
University of Chicago, IL, USA, and CEPR, London, UK
SUMMARY
We propose and apply a new approach for analyzing the effects of fiscal policy using vector autoregressions.
Specifically, we use sign restrictions to identify a government revenue shock as well as a government
spending shock, while controlling for a generic business cycle shock and a monetary policy shock. We
explicitly allow for the possibility of announcement effects, i.e., that a current fiscal policy shock changes
fiscal policy variables in the future, but not at present. We construct the impulse responses to three linear
combinations of these fiscal shocks, corresponding to the three scenarios of deficit-spending, deficit-financed
tax cuts and a balanced budget spending expansion. We apply the method to US quarterly data from 1955
to 2000. We find that deficit-financed tax cuts work best among these three scenarios to improve GDP, with
a maximal present value multiplier of five dollars of total additional GDP per each dollar of the total cut in
government revenue 5 years after the shock. Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
1. INTRODUCTION
What are the effects of tax cuts on the economy? How much does it matter whether they are
financed by corresponding cuts of expenditure or by corresponding increases in government debt,
compared to the no-tax-cut scenario? These questions are of key importance to the science of
economics and the practice of policy alike. This paper aims to answer these questions by proposing
and applying a new method of identifying fiscal policy surprises in vector autoregressions.
The identification method used in this paper is an extension of Uhlig (2005)’s agnostic
identification method of imposing sign restrictions on impulse response functions. We extend
this method to the identification of multiple fundamental shocks. More precisely, we identify a
government revenue shock as well as a government spending shock by imposing sign restrictions on
the fiscal variables themselves as well as imposing orthogonality to a generic business cycle shock
and a monetary policy shock, which are also identified with sign restrictions. No sign restrictions
are imposed on the responses of GDP, private consumption, private non-residential investment
and real wages to fiscal policy shocks, and so the method remains agnostic with respect to the
responses of the key variables of interest.
The identification method is thereby able to address three main difficulties which typically arise
in the identification of fiscal policy shocks in vector autoregressions. Firstly, there is the difficulty
of distinguishing movements in fiscal variables caused by fiscal policy shocks from those which are
simply the automatic movements of fiscal variables in response to other shocks such as business
cycle or monetary policy shocks. Secondly, there is the issue of what one means by a fiscal policy
Ł
Correspondence to: Andrew Mountford, Department of Economics, Royal Holloway, University of London, Egham
TW20 OEX, UK. E-mail: A.M[email protected]
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 961
shock. While there is agreement that a monetary policy shock entails a surprise rise in interest rates,
several competing definitions come to mind for fiscal policy shocks. Finally, one also needs to take
account of the fact that there is often a lag between the announcement and the implementation of
fiscal policy and that the announcement may cause movements in macroeconomic variables before
there are movements in the fiscal variables.
For the first problem we identify a business cycle shock and a monetary policy shock and
require that a fiscal shock be orthogonal to both of them. This filters out the automatic responses
of fiscal variables to business cycle and monetary policy shocks.
To address the second problem, we argue that macroeconomic fiscal policy shocks exist in a two-
dimensional space spanned by two basic shocks: a government revenue shock and a government
spending shock. Different fiscal policies such as balanced budget expansions can then be described
as different linear combinations of these two basic shocks. For example, a basic government
spending shock is defined as a shock where government spending rises for a defined period after
the shock, and which is orthogonal to the business cycle shock and the monetary policy shock.
We choose to restrict responses for a year following the shock in order to rule out shocks where
government spending rises on impact but then subsequently falls after one or two quarters. This
provides additional identifying power.
For the third problem, we also identify fiscal policy shocks with the identifying restriction that
the fiscal variable in question does not respond for four quarters, and then rises for a defined
period afterwards. Restricting the responses of impulse responses as a means of identification is
therefore particularly suitable for dealing with the announcement effect.
This paper therefore contributes to the recent and growing literature of employing vector
autoregressions to analyze the impact of fiscal policy shocks, complementing the existing large
literature analyzing monetary policy shocks; see, for example Leeper et al. (1996), Christiano
et al. (1999) and Favero (2001) for excellent surveys. Most of the previous literature has identified
fiscal shocks either by making assumptions about the sluggish reaction of some variables to fiscal
policy shocks (see, for example, Blanchard and Perotti, 2002; Fat
´
as and Mihov, 2001a,b; Favero,
2002; Gal
´
ı et al., 2007) or by using additional information such as the timing of wars, detailed
institutional information about the tax system and detailed historical study of policy decisions
or elections (see, for example, Ramey and Shapiro, 1998; Edelberg et al., 1999; Blanchard and
Perotti, 2002; Burnside et al., 2003; Eichenbaum and Fisher, 2004).
1
By contrast, this paper relies on macroeconomic time series data alone for shock identification
and does not rely on assumptions about the sluggish reaction of some variables to macroeconomic
shocks. Indeed it imposes no restrictions on the signs of the responses of the key variables of
interestGDP, private consumption, private non-residential investment and real wagesto fiscal
policy shocks. The approach of this paper thus sharply differentiates it from previous studies
and provides an important complementary method of analysis which, being a purely vector
autoregressive approach, is automatically systematic and can be universally applied.
The method of identifying policy shocks using sign restrictions on impulse responses has been
introduced and applied to monetary policy in Uhlig (2005). Uhlig’s method is extended here by
imposing orthogonality restrictions to the business cycle and monetary policy shocks as well as sign
restrictions. Faust (1998) uses sign restrictions to identify monetary policy shocks, imposing them
1
There are a wide variety of other empirical studies investigating the effects of fiscal policy. The focus of this paper is
on the analysis of the effects of fiscal policy using vector autoregressions and so we do not attempt to summarize this
literature here. For an excellent survey see Hemming et al. (2000).
Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
962 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
only at the time of impact, however, and Canova and De Nicol
`
o (2002, 2003) and Canova and Pina
(1998) identify monetary shocks using sign restrictions on impulse response correlations. Canova
and Pappa (2007) also identify fiscal shocks using sign restrictions on impulse response correlations
but control for monetary policy shocks using data from economies (states and countries) belonging
to monetary unions. More recently, Dedola and Neri (2007) have used sign restrictions to identify
technology shocks and Mountford (2005), Peersman (2005), Benati and Mumtaz (2007), Dungey
and Fry (2007) and Fry and Pagan (2007) have addressed the identification of multiple shocks
using sign restrictions.
We apply our new approach to US quarterly data, from 1955 to 2000. We use the same definitions
of government expenditure and revenue as Blanchard and Perotti (2002) in order not to obscure
the implications of our new methodological approach by using different data definitions. We show
that controlling for the business cycle shock is important when analyzing the consequences of
fiscal policy. By linearly combining our two base fiscal policy shocksi.e., the government
revenue shock and the government spending shockwe analyze three policy scenarios: deficit-
spending, deficit-financed tax cuts and a balanced budget spending expansion. Comparing these
three scenarios, we find that a surprise deficit-financed tax cut is the best fiscal policy to stimulate
the economy, giving rise to a maximal present value multiplier of five dollars of total additional
GDP per each dollar of the total cut in government revenue 5 years after the shock. Furthermore,
we find that deficit spending weakly stimulates the economy, that it crowds out private investment
without causing interest rates to rise, and that it does not cause a rise in real wages.
Despite the novel methodology developed in this paper, the results are reasonably similar to
those of the existing literature. As with Blanchard and Perotti (2002), we find that investment falls
in response to both tax increases and government spending increases and that the multipliers
associated with a change in taxes to be much higher than those associated with changes in
spending. This latter result also accords with the analysis of Romer and Romer (2007), who
find large effects from exogenous tax changes. With regard to private consumption we find, in
common with Blanchard and Perotti (2002) and Gal
´
ı et al. (2007), that consumption does not
fall in response to an unexpected increase in government spending. However, in contrast to these
studies we do not find that consumption rises strongly. Our results show that the response of
consumption is small and only significantly different from zero on impact and are thus more in
line with those of Burnside et al. (2003), who find that private consumption does not change
significantly in response to a positive spending shock.
2
Finally, we find that real wages do not rise
in response to an increase in government spending and have a negative response on impact and at
longer horizons. Thus the responses of investment, consumption and real wages to a government
spending shock are difficult to reconcile with the standard Keynesian approach, although they are
also not the responses predicted by the benchmark real business cycle model either.
As an open issue for future research, we leave the question as to how far the responses
calculated here are consistent with general equilibrium modeling, or whether additional restrictions
from general equilibrium modeling ought to be imposed during estimation. Chung and Leeper
(2007) have recently pointed out that long-run budget balance needs to hold and that this implies
restrictions on the VAR coefficients. Put differently, it ought to be obvious that one cannot forever
2
Theoretical explanations for why consumption does not fall in response to a government spending shock in an infinite
horizon framework are given by Devereux et al. (1996), in a model with increasing returns to scale and Gal
´
ı et al. (2007)
in a model with both sticky prices and ‘Non-Ricardian’ agents.
Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 963
stimulate the economy with deficit-financed tax cuts: they eventually need to be repaid. We agree
with Chung and Leeper that this issue is important and merits further attention.
The paper is comprised of three main sections. Section 2 describes the identification procedure
and the VAR. The empirically identified basic shocks are presented in Section 3, while Section 4
conducts policy analysis and compares the results with those of the existing literature in Section
4.6. The Appendix contains additional detail, in particular on the VAR framework and the sign
restriction methodology, as well as describing the data sources.
2. IDENTIFYING FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS
A fiscal policy shock is a surprise change in fiscal policy. However, there is no such thing as a
fiscal policy shock per se. Fiscal policy encompasses a wide variety of policies: there is an endless
list of types of incomes, for which the tax rules could be changed, or categories of government
spending, where changes could occur. In this paper we address the much broader and traditional
‘macro’-economic issue of the effects on the aggregate economy of aggregate fiscal variables.
Even so, there still remain a large set of possible policies since changes in fiscal policy could, for
example, be about changing the tax-debt mix for financing a given stream of government spending,
or about changing the level of spending for a given level of debt.
In this paper we view fiscal policy shocks as existing in a two-dimensional space spanned by two
basic impulse vectors: a government revenue shock and a government spending shock. We identify
each of these basic fiscal policy shocks by imposing a positive reaction of the impulse response of
the appropriate fiscal variablei.e., government revenue or government spending for quarters
k D 0,...,3 following the shock and by requiring it to be orthogonal to a business cycle shock
and a monetary policy shock, which in turn are also identified using sign restrictions. If we were
not to control for the state of the business cycle, it would be easy to end up confusing, for example,
an increase in government receipts due to a business cycle upturn with an upturn ‘caused’ by a
tax increase. Note that we do not require the two fiscal policy shocks to be mutually orthogonal.
Rather than simultaneously identifying all three (or all four) shocks, subject to the orthogonality
restrictions, we first identify the business cycle shock and monetary policy shock via a criterion
function based on the sign restrictions, thus ascribing as much movement as possible to these
shocks. The fiscal shocks are then identified via sign restrictions as well as the orthogonality
restrictions. This procedure may be reminiscent of a causal ordering. If the criterion function was
linear, one could linearly recombine the variables such that the first variable now corresponds to
that linear combination of the criterion function: a Cholesky decomposition would then make the
first shock explain as much as possible of the one-step-ahead prediction error in that first variable,
thus maximizing the criterion function. Since our criterion function is nonlinear and involves the
impulse responses for several periods, one could not rewrite the problem in this manner, but the
analogy may still be helpful to understand the procedure and the results.
A further thorny and well-understood challenge when identifying fiscal policy shocks is the
problem of the possible lag between the announcement and implementation of changes in fiscal
policy. Considering the potentially lengthy debates in legislatures about, say, a reduction in tax
rates, the change in government revenue is fairly predictable by the time the tax reduction actually
takes effect. Forward-looking individuals and firms can adjust their economic choices before that
date. While the tax change will happen eventually, the surprise of a change in fiscal policy
occurs earlier. Our identification procedure is easily adapted to deal with this problem by directly
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
964 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
identifying a shock for which there is a lag between the announcement and the implementation of
the change in fiscal policy. In particular, we shall identify announced fiscal policy shocks, where
government spending only rises in the fourth quarter following the shock but shows no reaction
beforehand.
3
Given the two basic fiscal shocks, different fiscal policy scenarios can be described as sequences
of different linear combinations of these two basic shocks. For example, we will define a balanced
budget expansionary fiscal scenario as a sequence of a linear combination of the two basic shocks
such that the increase in government spending is matched by the increase in tax revenue for a
sequence of five quarters, k D 0,...,4, following the initial shock.
2.1. The VAR and Identifying Restrictions
We use a VAR in GDP, private consumption, total government expenditure, total government
revenue, real wages, private non-residential investment, interest rate, adjusted reserves, the
producer price index for crude materials and the GDP deflator. The VAR system consists of
these 10 variables at a quarterly frequency from 1955 to 2000, has six lags, no constant or a time
trend, and uses the logarithm for all variables except the interest rate, where we have used the level.
The chosen approach largely dictates the choice of these variables. GDP, private consumption,
private investment and real wages are included as the focus of interest. Private consumption is also
included because the consumptionGDP ratio has predictive value for GDP, as Cochrane (1994)
has shown. Real wages are also included as Neoclassical and New Keynesian models tend to
predict different signs for the responses of real wages to deficit-spending shocks, with the former
predicting negative and the latter positive responses (see Ramey and Shapiro, 1998). The monetary
and price variables are there to identify monetary policy shocks. All the components of national
income are in real per capita terms. A more detailed description can be found in Appendix B.
The two fiscal variables in the VAR are defined in the same way as in Blanchard and Perotti
(2002). Thus total government expenditure is total government consumption plus total govern-
ment investment and total government revenues is total government tax revenues minus transfers.
Netting out transfer payments from the government revenue variable is a non-trivial decision, but
we have chosen to use Blanchard and Perotti’s (2002) data definitions in order to emphasize the
implications of the new identification technique rather than have the results obscured by using
different data definitions.
2.2. The Identifying Assumptions in Detail
An overview of our identifying sign restrictions on the impulse responses is provided in Table I.
A business cycle shock is defined as a shock which jointly moves output, consumption, non-
residential investment and government revenue in the same direction for four quarters following the
shock. Since we associate business cycles with the more substantial movements in these variables,
we identify the business cycle shock by a criterion function, which rewards large impulse responses
in the right directions more than small responses and penalizes responses of the wrong sign.
Such a co-movement is consistent with both demand and supply side shocks and hence the
approach remains ‘agnostic’ on the issue of the determinants of business cycle fluctuations. The
3
In this respect the identified shocks resemble a type of ‘news shock’ about fiscal policy and so are related to the shocks
identified by Beaudry and Portier (2003).
Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 965
Table I. Identifying sign restrictions
Gov. revenue Gov. spending GDP, cons, non-res.inv. Interest rate Adjusted reserves Prices
Non-fiscal shocks
Business cycle CC
Monetary policy C
Basic fiscal policy shocks
Government revenue C
Government spending C
This table shows the sign restrictions on the impulse responses for each identified shock. ‘Cons’ stands for private
consumption and ‘Non-res. inv.’ stands for non-residential investment. A C means that the impulse response of the
variable in question is restricted to be positive for four quarters following the shock, including the quarter of impact.
Likewise, a indicates a negative response. A blank entry indicates that no restrictions have been imposed.
restriction that government revenues increase with output in the business cycle shock should
be emphasized. This is our crucial identifying assumption for fiscal policy shocks: when output
and government revenues move in the same direction, we essentially assume that this must be
due to some improvement in the business cycle generating the increase in government revenue,
not the other way around. We regard this is as a reasonable assumption and consistent with a
number of theoretical views. Furthermore, our identifying assumptions are close to minimal: some
assumptions are needed to say anything at all. The orthogonality assumption a priori excludes the
view that positive co-movements of government revenues and output are caused by some form of
short term ‘Laffer curve’ or ‘fiscal consolidation’ effect from a surprise rise in taxes.
4
A monetary policy shock moves interest rates up and reserves and prices down for four quarters
after the shock. These identifying restrictions are close to those used in Uhlig (2005). We also
require the monetary policy shock to be orthogonal to the business cycle shock. The main purpose
of characterizing the business cycle and monetary shocks is to filter out the effects of these shocks
on the fiscal variables. The additional orthogonalization among these two shocks has no effect on
that.
Fiscal policy shocks are identified only through restricting the impulse responses of the fiscal
variables and through the requirement that they are orthogonal to both business cycle shocks
as well as monetary policy shocks. As stated above, we identify two basic fiscal shocksa
‘government spending shock’ and a ‘government revenue shock’ employing tight identifying
restrictions where the responses of fiscal variables are restricted for a defined period after the
shock. For example, a basic government spending shock is defined as a shock where government
spending rises for a year after the shock. These tight restrictions are designed to rule out very
transitory shocks to fiscal variables where, for example, government spending rises on impact
but falls after one or two quarters. Nonetheless we have checked that our results are robust to
weaker identifying restrictions where responses are only restricted on impact. Finally, it should be
noted that we do not restrict the behavior of government revenue when identifying the government
spending shock or vice versa. This is not necessary since all that is required to describe the two-
dimensional space of fiscal policy shocks are two linearly independent vectors. However, it is
4
The ‘Laffer curve’ is a phenomenon which, if it exists, may be expected to operate over the medium term and so would
not be ruled out by the short-run sign restrictions imposed. Indeed Figure 11 shows that the responses of government
revenue in response to a tax cut can be positive in the medium term. See Trabandt and Uhlig (2006), Giavazzi et al.
(1990, 2000) and Perotti (1999) for analysis on this issue.
Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
966 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
possible to place restrictions on these shocks so that, for example, government revenue’s response
to a government spending shock is initially zero. An example of such restrictions are the year
delayed fiscal shocks in Figures 5 and 8, where fiscal responses are restricted to be zero for a year
following the announcement of the shock.
Details on the estimation as well as on the implementation of the identification strategies,
including these zero restrictions, are described in Appendix A and in Mountford and Uhlig (2002).
3. RESULTS
The identified fundamental shocks for each time period are displayed in Figure 1. The shocks are
identified for each draw from the posterior and the 16th, 50th and 84th quantiles plotted. The
impulse responses for these fundamental shocks are shown in Figures 29, where we have plotted
the impulse responses of all our 10 variables to the shocks. The figures plot the 16th, 50th and
84th quantiles of these impulse responses, calculated at each horizon between 0 and 24 quarters
after the shocks. The impulses restricted by the identifying sign restrictions are identified by the
shaded area in the figures.
3.1. The Business Cycle Shock
The identified business cycle shocks are plotted in the first panel of Figure 1, where the NBER
recession dates are shaded. The identified shocks correspond well with the NBER dates, with the
only anomalies being the 198182 recession, which is not picked up, and the short 199091
recession, which does not appear to be very different in scale from other clusters of negative
shocks.
The impulse responses of the business cycle shock are plotted in Figure 2. In response
to the business cycle shock, output, consumption, non-residential investment and government
revenue increase in the first four quarters by construction. Given that no restriction is placed
on these responses after four periods, it is notable that all of these responses are persistent.
Government revenues increase approximately twice as much in percentage terms as GDP. There
is no contradiction here, provided marginal tax rates are approximately twice average tax rates.
The persistence in the non-residential investment variable indicates that a business cycle shock
may increase the steady-state capital to labor ratio and so generate a higher level of steady-
state income, consumption and government revenue. It must be stressed that these responses
are consistent with both demand and supply side explanations of the business cycle and this
paper is agnostic on the issue of the relative importance and persistence of demand and supply
shocks.
The responses of the monetary variables and the government spending variable to the business
cycle shock were not restricted at all by the identification method, and their responses are quite
interesting. The interest rate rises and the adjusted reserves fall in response to a positive business
cycle shock. This could be caused by a systematic counter-cyclical response of monetary policy
over the sample period, which ts with the description of monetary policy given by Romer and
Romer (1994). The fall in adjusted reserves (compared to the no-business-cycle-shock scenario)
would indicate that this counter-cyclical response is rather strong.
Government expenditures, in contrast, do not behave in a counter-cyclical fashion. Rather, they
increase, slowly, with a positive business cycle shock. Thus, if a business cycle boom fills the
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 967
5 2.5
0 2.5
5
Percent
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
Date
Business Cycle Shocks
5 2.5
0 2.5 5
Percent
1960 1970 1980 1990
2000
Date
Monetary Policy Shocks
5 2.5
0 2.5 5
Percent
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
Date
Government Revenue Shocks
5 2.5
0 2.5 5
Percent
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
Date
Government Spending Shocks
Figure 1. The shocks identified by the VAR: the business cycle shocks are identified first, the monetary policy
shocks are identified second and the government revenue and government spending shocks are identified third.
The shaded areas represent NBER recessions in the business cycle plot and a change of president in the
fiscal plots. This figure is available in color online at www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/jae
government’s coffers with cash, it will spend more eventually. Note again that, following Blanchard
and Perotti (2002), we chose the government expenditure variable to be government consumption
and investment in order to isolate changes in government expenditure from automatic changes over
the business cycle. Thus the government expenditure variable does not include transfer payments
which almost surely would automatically vary counter-cyclically.
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
968 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
-.5 0 .5 1 1.5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP
-.5 0 .5 1 1.5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
CONSUMPTION
-3 -1.5 0 1.5 3
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
-3 -1.5 0 1.5 3
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT REVENUE
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
REAL WAGES
-6 -3 0 3 6
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
NON-RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT
-.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
INTEREST RATE
-2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
ADJUSTED RESERVES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
PPIC
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP DEFLATOR
Figure 2. The business cycle shock ordered first. The shaded areas indicate the impulses directly restricted by
the identification procedure. This figure is available in color online at www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/jae
3.2. The M onetary Policy Shock
The identified monetary policy shocks are plotted in the second panel of Figure 1. Again these
identified shocks correspond well with the existing literature, such as Bernanke and Mihov’s (1998)
plot of monetary policy stance, and are on average negative (indicating a loose policy stance) in
the late 1970s, positive (indicating a tight policy stance) in the early 1980s, as well as being more
volatile in the Volcker experiment period, 197982.
The response to a monetary policy shock is shown in Figure 3. Note that we have constructed
the monetary policy shock to be orthogonal to the business cycle shock shown in Figure 2. Thus
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 969
-.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP
-.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
CONSUMPTION
-2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
-2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT REVENUE
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
REAL WAGES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
NON-RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT
-.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
INTEREST RATE
-3 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
ADJUSTED RESERVES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
Quarters After the Shock
PPIC
-2 -1 0 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
GDP DEFLATOR
Figure 3. The monetary policy shock ordered second. The shaded areas indicate the impulses directly restricted
by the identification procedure. This figure is available in color online at www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/
jae
this shock represents that part of the unanticipated quarterly change in monetary policy that
is not accounted for by systematic responses over the quarter to unanticipated business cycle
shocks. A consequence of our identification strategy is that if, rather counter-intuitively, monetary
policy shocks should be such that surprise rises in the interest rate cause short-term increases in
output, consumption and investment, then these effects would be captured by the business cycle
shock shown in Figure 2, not by the monetary shock shown here. Thus output, consumption and
investment in Figure 3 have a propensity to fall in the short term almost by construction and
they do, although interestingly by very little. Over the medium term, monetary policy shocks
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
970 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
-1 -.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP
-1 -.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
CONSUMPTION
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT REVENUE
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
REAL WAGES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
NON-RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT
-.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
INTEREST RATE
-2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
ADJUSTED RESERVES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
PPIC
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP DEFLATOR
Figure 4. The basic government revenue shock, identified by orthogonality to the business cycle shock and
monetary policy shock as well as a positive impulse response function of government revenues for four
quarters after the shock. The restriction is indicated by the shaded area on the graph. This figure is available
in color online at www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/jae
are associated with a marginally lower interest rate and increases in income, consumption and
wages. These results are thus not inconsistent with the findings in Uhlig (2005): there, without
orthogonality to the business cycle shock, sign restriction methods do not deliver a clear direction
for real GDP in response to a surprise rise in interest rates.
What is a little surprising is the rise in government revenue in response to the rise in interest
rates. One plausible, although not the only, explanation for this is that over the sample period
monetary and fiscal policy was coordinated so that a monetary tightening was accompanied by a
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 971
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
CONSUMPTION
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT REVENUE
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
REAL WAGES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
NON-RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT
-.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
INTEREST RATE
-2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
ADJUSTED RESERVES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
PPIC
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP DEFLATOR
Figure 5. The announced or anticipated basic government revenue shock, identified by orthogonality to
the business cycle shock and monetary policy shock as well as a zero impulse response for the first
four quarters and a positive impulse response function for the next four quarters of government revenues.
The restriction is indicated by the shaded area on the graph. This figure is available in color online at
www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/jae
fiscal tightening via an increase in taxes. If this were the case then there would be a danger that
requiring fiscal shocks to be orthogonal to monetary policy shocks will cause biases in the results.
For this reason we have checked the robustness of our identified fiscal shocks by identifying
them both second (orthogonal to only the business cycle shock) and third (orthogonal to both
the business cycle and monetary policy shocks). We find that the responses of the real variables
are very similar in both these specifications and hence any bias is small. This may be because
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
972 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
CONSUMPTION
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT REVENUE
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
REAL WAGES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
NON-RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT
-.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
INTEREST RATE
-2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
ADJUSTED RESERVES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
PPIC
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP DEFLATOR
Figure 6. A comparison of the median responses of an anticipated (solid line) and unanticipated (dashed line)
government revenue shock, where the impulses are plotted so that the time period of the implementation of
the tax rise is the same. This figure is available in color online at www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/jae
monetary policy shocks do not appear have a large effect on real macroeconomic variables. We
conclude from this that controlling for the monetary policy shock is not important when analyzing
the consequences of fiscal policy; see Mountford and Uhlig (2002) for a greater discussion of this
issue.
3.3. The B asic Government Revenue Shock
A basic government revenue shock is identified as a shock that is orthogonal to the business cycle
and monetary policy shock and where government revenue rises for a year after the shock. The
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 973
-1 -.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP
-1 -.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
CONSUMPTION
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT REVENUE
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
REAL WAGES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
NON-RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT
-.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
INTEREST RATE
-2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
ADJUSTED RESERVES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
PPIC
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP DEFLATOR
Figure 7. The basic government expenditure shock, identified by orthogonality to the business cycle shock
and monetary policy shock as well as a positive impulse response function of government expenditures for
four quarters after the shock. The restriction is indicated by the shaded area on the graph. This figure is
available in color online at www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/jae
identified government revenue shocks are plotted in the third panel of Figure 1, where the change
from shaded to non-shaded areas denotes changes in presidential terms. These identified shocks
correspond, in part at least, with Romer and Romer’s (2007) measure of exogenous tax changes,
in that the shocks are on average negative in the mid 1960s and mid 1980s and positive in the
early 1990s. They also clearly pick up the large effects of the 1975 Tax Reduction Act.
The impulse responses for this shock are displayed in Figure 4. Figure 4 shows that the responses
of the real variables of interest to a standard government revenue shock are intuitive. GDP,
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
974 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0
5 10
15 20
25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP
-1
-.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5
10
15
20
25
Quarters After the Shock
CONSUMPTION
-3 -2
-1 0 1 2
Percent
0
5 10
15 20
25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0
5
10
15
20
25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT REVENUE
-1
-.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0
5 10 15
20
25
Quarters After the Shock
REAL WAGES
-4 -2
0 2 4
Percent
0 5
10
15
20
25
Quarters After the Shock
NON-RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT
-.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10
15 20
25
Quarters After the Shock
INTEREST RATE
-2
-1 0 1 2
Percent
0
5 10 15 20
25
Quarters After the Shock
ADJUSTED RESERVES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0
5 10 15
20 25
Quarters After the Shock
PPIC
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5
10 15
20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP DEFLATOR
Figure 8. The announced or anticipated basic government expenditure shock, identified by orthogonality to
the business cycle shock and monetary policy shock as well as a zero impulse response for the first four
quarters and a positive impulse response function for the next four quarters of government expenditures.
The restriction is indicated by the shaded area on the graph. This figure is available in color online at
www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/jae
consumption and investment fall in response to an increase in revenue and real wages also fall,
although with a lag. The responses of interest rates and prices are less intuitive as interest rates
rise and reserves fall in response to a rise in revenue. Although no restriction is placed on the
behavior of government spending for this shock, government spending follows the shape of the
GDP and consumption responses and falls before recovering.
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 975
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
CONSUMPTION
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT REVENUE
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
REAL WAGES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
NON-RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT
-.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
INTEREST RATE
-2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
ADJUSTED RESERVES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
PPIC
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP DEFLATOR
Figure 9. A comparison of the median responses of an anticipated (solid line) and unanticipated (dashed line)
government spending shock, where the impulses are plotted so that the time period of the implementation
of the increase in government spending is the same.
3.4. The Anticipated Government Revenue Shock
We also identify a year delayed shock where government revenue is restricted to rise only after a
year.
5
The responses of this shock are displayed in Figure 5. They show an intuitive ‘announcement
5
The zero restrictions for government revenue for the anticipated tax shock implicitly assume that, should GDP fall in
response to this announcement, taxes are temporarily raised to cover the associated decline in revenues during the year
before implementation (see Leeper et al. 2008). It should be noted that these implicit tax rises should be depressing
GDP further and yet the negative response of GDP is small and so this consideration does not go against our finding
Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
976 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
effect’ as the anticipated rise in revenues immediately depresses output and consumption. This
accords with our intuition regarding the optimal smoothing behavior of individuals and firms.
Interest rates also fall with this drop in output, which is also intuitive.
6
The median responses of the unanticipated and anticipated shocks are compared in Figure 6,
where the responses of the unanticipated shocks are shifted forward so that the implementation of
the revenue shock is in the same time period. Figure 6 shows that the responses to an anticipated
government revenue shock, while similar to those of the unanticipated shocks in terms of their
sign, are somewhat smaller, perhaps because announced policies move fiscal variables by less than
unanticipated changes.
7
3.5. The B asic Government Spending Shock
A basic government revenue shock is identified as a shock that is orthogonal to the business
cycle and monetary policy shock and where government spending rises for a year after the shock.
The identified government spending shocks are plotted in the fourth panel of Figure 1, where the
change from shaded to non-shaded areas denotes changes in presidential terms. These identified
shocks show that government spending shocks were predominantly positive in the mid 1960s and
early 1990s and predominantly negative around 1960 and in the early 1970s. In the the 1990s
government spending appears to be more stable than average, with relatively few shocks reaching
the 2.5% level in absolute terms.
The impulse responses for this shock are displayed in Figure 7. Figure 7 shows that the basic
government spending shock stimulates output during the first four quarters, although only weakly,
and has only a very weak effect on private consumption. It also reduces investment, although
interestingly not via higher interest rates. Real wages do not respond positively to the government
spending shock and indeed are negative on impact and in the medium term, which is more in
accordance with neoclassical than New Keynesian models of government spending (see Ramey
and Shapiro, 1998). Although no restriction is placed on the behavior of government revenue, this
does not change very significantly and so the basic government spending shock will resemble a
fiscal policy shock of deficit spending, whose responses are displayed in Figure 10 below. The
response of prices to the increase in government spending is a little puzzling since both the
GDP deflator and the producer price index for crude materials show a decline. Although this is
a counter-intuitive result, it should be noted that this negative relationship between prices and
government spending has also been found in other studies (see, for example Canova and Pappa,
2007; Edelberg, et al., 1999. Fat
´
as and Mihov, 2001a).
that anticipated tax shocks have a much weaker response than unanticipated shocks. Further, note that an alternative
specification for the anticipated tax shock, which places no restrictions on tax revenues for the year before implementation,
could easily be implemented.
6
When analyzing anticipated tax shocks, we implicitly assume that our VAR approach approximates a time series model,
in which news about tax shocks are always about the next annual tax change and not about subsequent ones. Otherwise,
overlapping news or a moving average process for taxes with two or more lags may result in problems with invertibility
and an appropriate VAR representation, as Leeper et al. (2008) have shown.
7
Changes in fiscal policy may be the result of the systematic component of fiscal policyunrelated to the business
cycle rather fiscal policy shocks, as Liu et al. (2007) have argued is the case for monetary policy shocks. However, we
leave the joint identification of fiscal policy regime shifts and fiscal policy shock for future work.
Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 977
3.6. The Anticipated Government Spending Shock
We also identify a year delayed shock where government spending is restricted to rise only after
a year. The responses of this shock are displayed in Figure 8. They again show an intuitive
‘announcement’ effect on impact as the anticipated rise in spending immediately has a positive
effect on output and interest rates. Again this is consistent with smoothing behavior by individuals
and firms. The median responses of the unanticipated and anticipated shocks are compared
in Figure 9, where the responses of the unanticipated shocks are shifted forward so that the
implementation of the spending shock is in the same time period. Figure 9 shows that the responses
to an anticipated government spending shock appear more persistent and stronger than for the
unanticipated shocks and investment is no longer crowded out by the increase in government
spending. This is an interesting and slightly puzzling result; however, it should be noted that the
interpretation of these responses in the medium term is clouded by the marginal cut in taxes after
a year. From Figure 5 this would have a significant expansionary effect and this may be the cause
of the persistent positive effects on income and consumption. In Section 4.1 below we demonstrate
a straightforward method for accounting for such changes when performing policy analysis.
4. POLICY ANALYSIS
We can use the basic shocks identified in the previous section to analyze the effects of different
fiscal policies. We view different fiscal policy shocks as different linear combinations of the basic
fiscal policy shocks. There are clearly a huge number of possible scal policies we could analyze,
so here we restrict ourselves to comparing three popularly analyzed fiscal policies. A deficit-
spending shock, a deficit financed tax cut and a balanced budget spending shock. We first detail
how the impulse responses for these policies are generated.
4.1. CALCULATING THE IMPULSE RESPONSES FOR DIFFERENT FISCAL POLICY
SCENARIOS
Our methodology regards different fiscal policy scenarios as being different combinations of the
two basic shocks over a sequence of several quarters. For example, a government spending scenario
where government spending is raised by 1% for four quarters while government revenue remains
unchanged is the linear combination of the sequence of the two basic shocks that generates these
responses in the fiscal variables as the combined impulse response. More formally, denoting r
j,a
k
as the response at horizon k of variable j to the impulse vector a, then the above policy requires
that
0.01 D
k
jD0
r
GS,BGS
k jBGS
j
C r
GS,BGR
k jBGR
j
for k D 0,...K
0 D
k
jD0
r
GR,BGS
k jBGS
j
C r
GR,BGR
k jBGR
j
for k D 0,...K
where K D 4, GS and GR stand for government expenditure and government revenue, and BGS
j
and BGR
j
are respectively the scale of the standard basic government spending and revenue shocks
in period j.
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
978 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
-1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP
-1 -.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
CONSUMPTION
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
-6 -3 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT REVENUE
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
REAL WAGES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
NON-RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT
-.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
INTEREST RATE
-2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
ADJUSTED RESERVES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
PPIC
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP DEFLATOR
.50-.5
Figure 10. The deficit spending policy scenario where government spending is raised by 1% for four
quarters with government revenues remaining unchanged. These impulses are linear combinations of a
sequence of the basic shocks displayed in Figures 4 and 7. This figure is available in color online at
www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/jae
We analyze three key policy scenarios below: deficit spending, a deficit-financed tax cut and a
balanced budget spending expansion. It should be clear, however, that other scenarios of interest
can be analyzed in this manner as well.
4.2. A Deficit-Spending Fiscal Policy Scenario
The impulse responses for a deficit spending fiscal policy scenario are shown in Figure 10. The
policy scenario is designed as a sequence of basic fiscal shocks such that government spending
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 979
rises by 1% and tax revenues remain unchanged for four quarters following the initial shock.
As noted above, the standard basic government spending shock does not change tax revenues
significantly, so the impulses in Figure 10 and are similar to those in Figure 7. Thus the deficit
spending scenario stimulates output and consumption during the first four quarters although only
weakly, it reduces non-residential investment and it produces a counter-intuitive response for
prices.
4.3. A Deficit-Financed Tax Cut Fiscal Policy Scenario
The impulse responses for a deficit financed tax cut fiscal policy scenario are shown in Figure 11.
The policy scenario is designed as a sequence of basic fiscal shocks such that tax revenues fall by
1% and government spending remains unchanged for four quarters (including the initial quarter)
following the initial shock. The responses look very similar to a mirror image of the responses to
the basic government revenue shock in Figure 4. Thus the tax cut stimulates output, consumption
and investment significantly, with the effect peaking after about 3 years. The effect on prices is
initially negative but subsequently positive following the rise in output.
4.4. The Balanced B udget Spending Policy Scenario
The balanced budget spending policy scenario is identified by requiring both government revenues
and expenditures to increase in such a way that the increase in revenues and expenditure is equal
for each period in the four-quarter window following the initial shock. For ease of comparison
we choose a sequence of basic fiscal shocks such that government spending rises by 1% and
government revenue rises by 1.28%. Government revenue rises by more than government spending
since over the sample government revenue’s share of GDP is 0.162, while that of government
spending is 0.208; thus we require government revenue to rise by (0.208/0.162)%. The results
are shown in Figure 12. These show that on impact there is a small expansionary effect on GDP
but thereafter the depressing effects of the tax increases dominate the spending effects, and GDP,
consumption and investment fall.
4.5. Measures of the Effects of Policy Scenarios
To compare the effects of one fiscal scenario with another it is useful to define summary measures
of the effects of each fiscal scenario. One measure used in the literature is the ratio of the response
of GDP at a given period to the initial movement of the fiscal variable (see, for example, Blanchard
and Perotti, 2002; Canova and Pappa, 2007). We refer to this as the impact multiplier. We report
the impact multipliers of the deficit financed tax cut and deficit-spending policy scenarios below
in Tables III and IV.
However, we think a measure of the impact of a scenario along the entire path of the responses
up to a given period is also useful. In Figure 13 we have therefore plotted the present value of
the impulse responses of GDP and the fiscal variables for the deficit-financed tax cut and the
deficit-spending policy scenarios. We have also calculated a present value multiplier for these
scenarios, which we display in Table II. To calculate the present value multiplier we use the
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
980 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
-.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP
-.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
CONSUMPTION
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT REVENUE
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
REAL WAGES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
NON-RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT
-.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
INTEREST RATE
-2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
ADJUSTED RESERVES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
PPIC
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP DEFLATOR
Figure 11. The deficit-financed tax cut policy scenario where government spending remains unchanged
and government revenue is reduced by 1% for four quarters. These impulses are linear combinations of
a sequence of the basic shocks displayed in Figures 4 and 7. This figure is available in color online at
www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/jae
following formula:
Present value multiplier at lag k D
k
jD0
1 C i
j
y
j
k
jD0
1 C i
j
f
j
1
f/y
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 981
-1.5 -1 -.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP
-1.5 -1 -.5 0 .5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
CONSUMPTION
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT SPENDING
-6 -3 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GOVERNMENT REVENUE
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
REAL WAGES
-6 -4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
NON-RESIDENTIAL INVESTMENT
-.5 0 .5
Percent
0
5
10
15
20
25
Quarters After the Shock
INTEREST RATE
-2 -1 0 1 2
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
ADJUSTED RESERVES
-4 -2 0 2 4
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
PPIC
-1 -.5 0 .5 1
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
GDP DEFLATOR
Figure 12. The balanced budget policy scenario where government spending is raised by 1% for four quarters
and government revenues raised so that the increased revenue matches the increased spending. These impulses
are linear combinations of a sequence of the basic shocks displayed in Figures 4 and 7. This figure is available
in color online at www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/jae
where y
j
is the response of GDP at period j, f
j
is the response of the fiscal variable at period j,
i is the average interest rate over the sample, and f/y is the average share of the fiscal variable in
GDP over the sample. We use the median multiplier in all cases.
Table II and Figure 13 and tell the same story. They show that in present value terms tax cuts
have a much greater effect on GDP than government spending. The present value of the GDP
response to a deficit spending scenario becomes insignificant after 2 years, whereas that for the
deficit-financed tax cut is significantly positive throughout. Figure 13 also shows that the standard
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
982 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
-2 0 2 4 6 8 10 12
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
DISCOUNTED CUMULATIVE GOVT SPENDING
-12 -9 -6 -3 0 1.5
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
DISCOUNTED CUMULATIVE GDP RESPONSES
DEFICIT SPENDING
-10 -5 0 5 10 15 20
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
DISCOUNTED CUMULATIVE GOVT REVENUE
-1 0 2 4 6 8 10 12
Percent
0 5 10 15 20 25
Quarters After the Shock
DISCOUNTED CUMULATIVE GDP RESPONSES
DEFICIT FINANCED TAX CUT
DISCOUNTED CUMULATIVE RESPONSES TO POLICY SHOCKS
Figure 13. The present value of the impulses for GDP and the changing fiscal variable for the deficit-spending
policy scenario and the deficit-financed tax cut policy scenario displayed in Figures 10 and 11. This figure
is available in color online at www.interscience.wiley.com/journal/jae
Table II. Present value multipliers of the policy scenarios
1 qrt 4 qrts 8 qrts 12 qrts 20 qrts Maximum
Deficit-financed tax cut 0.29 0.52 1.63 5.25 4.55 5.25 (qrt 12)
Deficit spending 0.65 0.46 0.07 0.26 2.07 0.65 (qrt 1)
This table shows the present value multipliers for a deficit financed tax cut policy scenario and for a deficit-spending
fiscal policy scenario. The multipliers given are the median multipliers in both cases.
Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 983
error of the present value multiplier becomes very large for the deficit-financed tax cut at later
time periods.
8
4.6. Comparison of Results with the Existing Literature
Despite the novel methodology used in this paper, there are many similarities to results obtained
elsewhere in the existing literature. There are, however, also important differences, which we shall
discuss below. As we have used Blanchard and Perotti’s (2002) data definitions for the fiscal
variables and use a very similar sample period, it is natural to compare our results most closely
with their paper. We do this in the following subsection. We compare our results to other studies
in a further subsection.
4.6.1 Comparison with Blanchard and Perotti (2002)
The impact multipliers, defined above, are compared with those of Blanchard and Perotti (2002)
in Tables III and IV.
For the deficit-financed tax cut, Table III shows that our results are very comparable with
Blanchard and Perotti’s. In both studies the effect on output of a change in tax revenues is
persistent and large. The size of the impact multiplier is greater in our results than in Blanchard
and Perotti’s, although in both studies the impact multipliers of the tax cut scenario are greater
than those of the spending scenario.
For the spending scenario, Table IV shows that size of the impact multipliers associated with
increased government spending is smaller than Blanchard and Perotti’s, but that the timing has a
similar pattern in the sense that the largest impact multipliers are in the periods close to the impact
of the initial shock and with the responses after a year being insignificant.
With respect to the responses of investment again the two studies are similar. In both Blanchard
and Perotti’s and in our study investment falls in response to both tax increases and government
Table III. Impact multipliers of deficit-financed tax cut policy scenarios
1 qrt 4 qrts 8 qrts 12 qrts 20 qrts Maximum
Mountford and Uhlig
GDP 0.28 0.93 2.05 3.41 2.59 3.57 (qrt 13)
Tax revenues 1.00 1.00 0.06 1.05 1.03
Gov. spending 0.00 0.00 0.27 0.43 0.48
Blanchard and Perotti
(2002)
GDP 0.70 1.07 1.32 1.30 1.29 1.33 (qrt 7)
Tax revenues 0.74 0.31 0.17 0.16 0.16
Gov. spending 0.06 0.10 0.17 0.20 0.20
This table shows the impact multipliers for a deficit-financed tax cut fiscal scenario for various quarters after the initial
shock and compares them to similar measures from Blanchard and Perotti (2002 Table III). The multiplier represents the
effect in dollars of a one-dollar cut in taxes at the first quarter. For the Mountford and Uhlig results this is calculated
with the formula: Multiplier for GDP D
GDP response
Initial fiscal shock
/(Average fiscal variable share of GDP), where the median
responses are used in all cases. On the calculation of the Blanchard and Perotti (2002) multipliers see Blanchard and
Perotti (2002 section V).
8
The median multiplier becomes negative at later time periods for both the deficit spending and deficit-financed tax cut
shocks but in both cases these negative multipliers are not significant.
Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
984 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
Table IV. Impact multipliers of a deficit-spending policy scenario
1 qrt 4 qrts 8 qrts 12 qrts 20 qrts Maximum
Mountford and Uhlig
GDP 0.65 0.27 0.74 1.19 2.24 0.65 (qrt 1)
Gov. spending 1.00 1.00 0.90 0.37 0.32
Tax revenues 0.00 0.00 0.33 0.87 2.04
Blanchard and Perotti
(2002)
GDP 0.90 0.55 0.65 0.66 0.66 0.90 (qrt 1)
Gov. spending 1.00 1.30 1.56 1.61 1.62
Tax revenues 0.10 0.18 0.33 0.36 0.37
This table shows the impact multipliers for a deficit-spending fiscal scenario for various quarters after the initial shock
and compares them to similar measures from Blanchard and Perotti (2002 Table IV). The multiplier represents the effect
in dollars of a one-dollar increase in spending at the first quarter. For the Mountford and Uhlig results this is calculated
with the formula: Multiplier for GDP D
GDP response
Initial fiscal shock
/(Average fiscal variable share of GDP), where the median
responses are used in all cases. On the calculation of the Blanchard and Perotti (2002) multipliers see Blanchard and
Perotti (2002 section V).
spending increases. With regard to consumption the results have some similarities to Blanchard and
Perotti’s in that consumption does not fall in response to a spending shock. However, in Blanchard
and Perotti (2002) consumption rises significantly in response to a spending shock, whereas in our
analysis consumption does not move by very much.
9
As Figure 10 shows, consumption’s response
is only significantly positive on impact and then by only a small amount. Thereafter its response is
insignificant. Finally, we find that real wages do not rise in response to an increase in government
spending and have a negative response on impact and at longer horizons. Thus, taken together,
these findings are difficult to reconcile with the standard Keynesian approach, although they are
also not the responses predicted by the benchmark real business cycle model.
4.6.2 Comparison with Other Studies
With regard to other studies in the literature, not only are there differences in methodology but
also in the definitions of the scal variables. There is thus no shortage of potential sources for
differences in results. Nevertheless, there is still some common ground in the results of this paper
and previous work. For example, consider the recent work by Burnside et al. (2003), which builds
on the work of Ramey and Shapiro (1998) and Edelberg et al. (1999) in using changes in military
purchases associated with various wars to identify government spending shock. They find that
private consumption does not change significantly in response to a government spending shock.
However, in contrast to our results they find that investment has an initial, transitory positive
response to the spending shock.
4.7. Variance of the Policy Analysis
Clearly there is a considerable degree of uncertainty in the numbers displayed in Tables III and IV,
as they are based on the maximum multipliers from the median impulse responses. An advantage
of the Bayesian approach used in our analysis is that it naturally provides a measure of the standard
9
See also Gali et al. (2007), who also find a significantly positive consumption response.
Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 985
errors for this policy analysis. Standard errors can easily be calculated for each policy scenario by
taking the maximum and minimum multipliers of GDP and their corresponding lag for each of
the draws from the posterior. These maxima and minima can then be ordered and the 16th, 50th
and 84th percentiles reported. This is done in Table V.
Table V supports the conclusions above. The maximum expansionary effect of a deficit-spending
scenario is much below that of the tax revenue scenario. Indeed the upper confidence limit of the
deficit-spending scenario is below the lower confidence limit of the tax cut scenario. For the tax
cut the maximum effects are significantly positive and the minimum effects are insignificantly
different from zero.
The results in Table V are usefully related to the impulse responses in Figures 1012. For
the tax cut the maximum multipliers occur after two or more years, whereas for the balanced
budget and deficit-spending scenarios the maximum effects occur at short lags and the minimum
effects at longer lags. Since the variance of the impulse responses for these scenarios appears to
increase at longer lag lengths, we also look at the maximum and minimum multipliers of the two
spending scenarios in the first year after the initial shock. In this case we now get the result that
the deficit-spending scenario’s minimum multiplier is insignificantly different from zero but that
for the balanced budget spending scenario is still significantly negative.
These statistics relate to the distribution of the maximum and minimum impact multiplier
effects of each fiscal scenario. For each draw the maximum and minimum fiscal multiplier is
calculated and the 16th, 50th and 84th percentiles of these results are displayed. The multiplier
statistic is calculated in terms of the initial, lag 0, fiscal shock as follows: multiplier for
GDP D
GDP response
Fiscal shock at Lag 0
/(Average fiscal variable share of GDP).
4.8. Policy Conclusions
An important lesson one can draw from the results is that while a deficit-financed expenditure
stimulus is possible, the eventual costs are likely to be much higher than the immediate benefits.
Suppose that government spending is increased by 2%, financed by increasing the deficit: this
results, using the median values from Table V, at maximum, in less than a 2% increase in GDP. But
the increased deficit needs to be repaid eventually with a hike in taxes. Even ignoring compounded
Table V. Maximum and minimum impact multipliers of fiscal policy scenarios
Fiscal scenario Maximum multiplier Minimum multiplier
Median
multiplier
Confidence interval
16th, 84th quantiles
Median
multiplier
Confidence interval
16th, 84th quantiles
Deficit spending 0.91 0.68, 1.37 2.88 4.99, 0.80
lag 4 lag 2, lag 6 at lag 20 lag 24, lag 8
Balanced budget 0.47 0.19, 0.84 5.84 9.46, 3.63
lag 1 lag 1, lag 1 at lag 19 lag 15, lag 11
Tax cut 3.81 2.58, 5.49 0.19 0.11, 0.36
lag 12 lag 15, lag 13 at lag 24 lag 24, lag 1
Deficit spending 0.79 0.59, 1.05 0.09 0.21, 0.31
in first year lag 4 lag 4, lag 1 at lag 4 lag 4, lag 2
Balanced budget 0.45 0.16, 0.79 0.71 1.11, 0.40
in first year at lag 3 lag 1, lag 1 at lag 4 lag 1, lag 2
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
986 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
interest rates, this would require a tax hike of over 2%.
10
This tax hike results in a greater than
7% drop in GDP. Thus, unless the policy maker’s discount rate is very high, the costs of the
expansion will be much higher than the initial benefit.
This general line of reasoning is consistent with the balanced budget spending scenario
whose impulses are shown in Figure 12. This shows that when government spending is financed
contemporaneously the contractionary effects of the tax increases outweigh the expansionary effects
of the increased expenditure after a very short time.
5. CONCLUSION
In this paper we have presented a new approach for distinguishing the effects of fiscal policy
shocks by adapting the method of Uhlig (2005). This method uses only the information in the
macroeconomic time series of the vector autoregression together with minimal assumptions to
identify fiscal policy shocks. In particular, it imposes no restrictions on the signs of the responses
of the key variables of interestGDP, private consumption, real wages and private non-residential
investmentto fiscal policy shocks. The paper applied this approach using post-war data on the
US economy.
We have analyzed three types of policy scenarios: a deficit-financed spending increase, a
balanced budget spending increase (financed with higher taxes) and a deficit-financed tax cut,
in which revenues increase but government spending stays unchanged. We found that a deficit-
spending scenario stimulates the economy for the first four quarters but only weakly compared
to that for a deficit-financed tax cut. We also found that both types of spending scenario had the
effect of crowding out investment.
Although the best scal policy for stimulating the economy appears to be deficit-financed tax
cuts, we wish to point out that this should not be read as endorsing them. This paper only points
out that unanticipated deficit-financed tax cuts work as a (short-lived) stimulus to the economy,
not that they are sensible. The resulting higher debt burdens may have long-term consequences
which are far worse than the short-term increase in GDP, and surprising the economy may not
be good policy in any case. These normative judgements require theoretical models for which the
empirical positive results in this paper can provide a useful starting point.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
This paper is a substantially revised version of the CEPR discussion paper No 3338. This research
has been sponsored by the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft through the SFB 649 ‘Economic
Risk’ and by the RTN networks NASEF and MAPMU. We are grateful to comments by seminar
audiences at Royal Holloway, Exeter University, Milan, an NASEF meeting on Hydra, an SFB 373
meeting in Wulkow, a conference in Alicante, Southampton University and the London Business
School. Special thanks go to Greg Mankiw for pointing out an important issue in an earlier version
of this paper, which we have now resolved.
10
For simplicity, we are assuming the tax hike to be a surprise, when it occurs, which allows us to use the results above.
Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 987
REFERENCES
Beaudry P, Portier F. 2003. Stock prices, news and economic fluctuations. Mimeo, University of Toulouse.
Benati L, Mumtaz H. 2007. US evolving macroeconomic dynamics: a structural investigation. Working Paper
Series No. 746, European Central Bank.
Bernanke BS. 1986. Alternative explanations of the moneyincome correlation. In Real Business Cycles,
Real Exchange Rates, and Actual Policies, Brunner K, Meltzer A (eds). Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy, no. 25. North-Holland: Amsterdam.
Bernanke BS, Mihov I. 1998. Measuring monetary policy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(3): 869890.
Blanchard O. 1997. Macroeconomics. Prentice-Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
Blanchard O, Perotti R. 2002. An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government
spending and taxes on output. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117(4): 13291368.
Blanchard OJ, Quah D. 1989. The dynamic effects of aggregate demand and supply disturbances. American
Economic Review 79(September): 655673.
Blanchard O, Watson M. 1986. Are all Business cycles alike? In R.J. Gordon, ed., The American Business
Cycle, Gordon RJ (ed.). University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL; 123160.
Burnside C, Eichenbaum M, Fisher JDM. 2003. Fiscal shocks and their consequences. Working Paper 9772,
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Canova F, De Nicol
´
o G. 2002. Monetary disturbances matter for business fluctuations in the G7. Journal of
Monetary Economics 49: 11311159.
Canova F, De Nicol
´
o G. 2003. On the sources of business cycles in the G7. Journal of International
Economics 59: 77100.
Canova F, Pappa E. 2007. Price differentials in monetary unions: the role of fiscal shocks. Economic Journal
117: 713737.
Canova F, Pina J. 1998. Monetary policy misspecification in VAR models. Working paper, CEPR.
Christiano LJ, Eichenbaum M, Evans C. 1999. Monetary policy shocks: what have we learned and to what
end? Handbook of Monetary Economics, Woodford M, Taylor J (eds). Northwestern University: Evanston,
IL.
Chung H, Leeper EM. 2007. What has financed government debt? Working Paper No. W13425, NBER.
Cochrane JH. 1994. Permanent and transitory components of GNP and stock prices. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 109(1): 241265.
Dedola L, Neri S. 2007. What does a technology shock do? A VAR analysis with model-based sign
restrictions. Journal of Monetary Economics 54(2): 512549.
Devereux MB, Head AC, Lapham M. 1996. Monopolistic competition, increasing returns and the effects of
government spending. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 28: 233254.
Dungey M, Fry R. 2007. The identification of fiscal and monetary Policy in a structural VAR. M, Wo rking
Paper No. 292007, CAMA.
Edelberg W, Eichenbaum M, Fisher JDM. 1999. Understanding the effects of a shock to government
purchases. Review of Economic Dynamics 2: 166206.
Eichenbaum M, Fisher JDM. 2004. Fiscal policy in the aftermath of 9/11. Working Paper 32704,Northwest-
ern University.
Fat
´
as A, Mihov I. 2001a. Fiscal policy and business cycles: an empirical investigation. Moneda y Credito
212: 167210.
Fat
´
as A, Mihov I. 2001b. The effects of fiscal policy on consumption and employment: theory and evidence.
Draft, INSEAD.
Faust J. 1998. On the robustness of the identified VAR conclusions about money. Carnegie Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy 49: 207244.
Favero C. 2001. Applied Macroeconometrics. Oxford University Press: Oxford.
Favero C. 2002. How do European monetary and fiscal authorities behave? Draft, IGIER, Bocconi University.
Fry R, Pagan A. 2007. Some issues in using sign restrictions for identifying structural VARs. Working Paper
No. 14, NCER.
Gal
´
ı J. 1992. How well does the IS-LM model fit postwar US data? Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(2):
709738.
Gal
´
ıJ,L
´
opez-Salido JD, Vall
´
es J. 2007. Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption.
Journal of the European Economic Association 5(1): 227270.
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
988 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
Giavazzi F, Jappelli T, Pagano M. 1990. Can severe fiscal contractions be expansionary? Tales of two
small European countries. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Blanchard OJ, Fisher S (eds). MIT Press:
Cambridge, MA; 75 110.
Giavazzi F, Pagano M. 2000. Searching for non-linear effects of fiscal policy: evidence from industrial and
developing countries. European Economic Review 44: 1259 1289.
Hemming R, Kell M, Mahfouz S. 2000. The effectiveness of fiscal policy in stimulating economic activity:
a review of the literature. Mimeo, International Monetary Fund.
Leeper E, Sims C, Zha T. 1996. What does monetary policy do? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 2:
163.
Leeper E, Walker TB, Yang S-CS. 2008. Fiscal foresight: analytics and econometrics. Mimeo, Indiana
University.
Liu Z, Waggoner DF, Zha T. 2007. Expectation effects of regimes shifts in monetary policy. Kiel Wo rking
Papers 1357, Kiel Institute for the World Economy.
Mountford A, Uhlig H. 2002. What are the effects of fiscal policy shocks? Discussion Papers No. 3338,
CEPR.
Mountford A. 2005. Leaning into the wind: a structural VAR investigation of UK monetary policy. Oxford
Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 67(5): 597621.
Peersman G. 2005. What caused the early millennium slowdown? Evidence based on vector autoregression.
Journal of Applied Econometrics 20(2): 185207.
Perotti R. 1999. Fiscal policy in good times and bad. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 114(4): 13991436.
Ramey V, Shapiro M. 1998. Costly capital reallocation and the effects of government spending. In Carnegie
Rochester Conference on Public Policy.
Romer DH, Romer C. 1994. What ends recessions? NBER Macroeconomics Annual 9: 1357.
Romer DH, Romer C. 2007. The macroeconomic effects of tax changes: estimates based on a new measure
of fiscal shocks. Working Paper No. 13264 , NBER.
Sims CA. 1986. Are forecasting models usable for policy analysis? Minneapolis Federal Reserve Bank
Quarterly Review Winter: 2 16.
Sims CA, Zha T. 1998. Bayesian methods for dynamic multivariate models. International Economic Review
39(4): 949968.
Trabandt M, Uhlig H. 2006. How far are we from the slippery slope? The Laffer curve revisited. SFB 649
Discussion Paper No. 2006-023.
Uhlig H. 2005. What are the effects of monetary policy? Results from an agnostic identification procedure.
Journal of Monetary Economics 52: 381419.
APPENDIX A: VARS AND IMPULSE MATRICES
A VAR in reduced form is given by
Y
t
D
L
iD1
B
i
Y
ti
C u
t
,t D 1,....T, E[u
t
u
0
t
] D
where Y
t
are m ð 1vectors,L is the lag length of the VAR, B
i
are m ð m coefficient matrices and
u
t
is the one-step-ahead prediction error.
The problem of identification is to translate the one-step-ahead prediction errors, u
t
,into
economically meaningful, or ‘fundamental’, shocks,
v
t
. We adopt the common assumptions in the
VAR literature that there are m fundamental shocks, which are mutually orthogonal and normalized
to be of variance 1. Thus E[
v
t
v
0
t
] D I
m
. Identification of these shocks amounts to identifying a
matrix A, such that u
t
D Av
t
and AA
0
D .Thejth column of A represents the immediate impact,
or impulse vector, of a one standard error innovation to the jth fundamental innovation, which is
the jth element of
v. The following definition is useful, and new.
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 989
Definition 1 An impulse matrix of rank n is a n ð m sub-matrix of some m ð m matrix A, such
that AA
0
D . An impulse vector a is an impulse matrix of rank 1, i.e., a vector a 2
m
such that
there exists some matrix A, where a is a column of A, such that AA
0
D .
One can show that the identification does not depend on the particular matrix A chosen beyond
a given impulse matrix, i.e., a given impulse matrix uniquely identifies the fundamental shocks
corresponding to it.
Theorem 1 Suppose that is regular. Let a given impulse matrix [a
1
,...,a
n
] of size n be
a submatrix of two m ð m matrices A,
Q
A with AA
0
D
Q
A
Q
A
0
D .Letv
t
D A
1
u
t
, Qv
t
D
Q
A
1
u
t
and let
v
1
t
,...,v
n
t
resp. Qv
1
t
,...,Qv
n
t
be the entries in v
t
resp. Qv
t
corresponding to a
1
,...,a
n
, i.e., if,
for example, a
1
is the third column of A, then v
1
t
is the third entry of v
t
. Then, v
i
t
DQv
i
t
for all
i D 1,...,n.
Proof Without loss of generality, let [a
1
,...,a
n
]bethefirstn columns of A and
Q
A.Ifthisis
for example, not the case for A and if, for example, a
1
is the third column of A, one can find
a permutation matrix P so that the given impulse matrix will be the first n columns of
O
A D AP
with a
1
the first column of
O
A.SincePP
0
D I,
O
A
O
A
0
D . Furthermore, the first column of P is
the vector e
3
, which is zero except for a 1 in its third entry: hence the first entry of
O
A
1
u
t
D P
0
v
t
must be the third entry of v
t
and thus be v
1
t
corresponding to a
1
.
With [a
1
,...,a
n
]asthefirstn columns of A and
Q
A,letE
n
D [I
n
, 0
n,m
]. Note that
[
v
1
t
,...,v
n
t
]
0
D E
n
A
1
u
t
.WeneedtoshowthatE
n
A
1
u
t
D E
n
Q
A
1
u
t
for all u
t
.Itsufcesto
show that E
n
A
1
D E
n
Q
A
1
,since is regular. But this follows from
E
n
A
1
D E
n
A
1
AA
0
D E
n
A
0
D [a
1
,...,a
n
]
0
D E
n
Q
A
1
Q
A
Q
A
0
D E
n
Q
A
1
In the VAR literature identification usually proceeds by identifying all m fundamental shocks
and so characterizing the entire A matrix. This requires imposing mm 1/2 restrictions on the
A matrix. This is done either by assuming a recursive ordering of variables in the VAR, so that
a Cholesky decomposition of A can be used (see Sims, 1986), or by imposing the mm 1/2
restrictions via assumed short-run structural relationships as in Bernanke (1986) and Blanchard and
Watson (1986), via assumed long-run structural relationships, as in Blanchard and Quah (1989) or
via both assumed short-run and long-run structural relationships as in Gal
´
ı (1992).
This paper instead extends the method of Uhlig (2005) and identifies at most three fundamental
shocks and so needs to characterize an impulse matrix [a
1
,a
2
,a
3
] of rank 3 rather than all
of A. This is accomplished by imposing sign restrictions on the impulse responses. Note that, by
construction, the covariance between the fundamental shocks
v
1
t
, v
2
t
and v
3
t
corresponding to
a
1
,a
2
and a
3
is zero, i.e., that these fundamental shocks are orthogonal.
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
990 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
To that end, note that any impulse matrix [a
1
,...,a
n
] can be written as the product
[a
1
,...,a
n
] D
Q
AQ of the lower triangular Cholesky factor
Q
A of with an n ð m matrix
Q D [q
1
,...,q
n
] of orthonormal rows q
i
, i.e., QQ
0
D I
n
: this follows from noting that
Q
A
1
A must be an orthonormal matrix for any decomposition AA
0
D of . Likewise, Let
a D a
s
,s 2f1,...,ng be one of the columns of the impulse matrix and q D q
s
D
Q
A
1
a
s
be
the corresponding column of Q: note that q
s
does not depend on the other a
p
,p 6D s.Asin
Uhlig (2005), it follows easily that the impulse responses for the impulse vector a can be written
as a linear combination of the impulse responses to the Cholesky decomposition of as follows.
Define r
ji
k as the impulse response of the jth variable at horizon k to the ith column of
Q
A,and
the m-dimensional column vector r
i
k as [r
1i
k,...,r
mi
k]. Then the m-dimensional impulse
response r
a
k at horizon k to the impulse vector a
s
is given by
r
a
k D
m
iD1
q
i
r
i
k 1
(where q
i
is the ith entry of q D q
s
).
Define the function f on the real line per fx D 100x if x ½ 0andfx D x if x 0. Let s
j
be
the the standard error of variable j.LetJ
S1C
be the index set of variables for which identification
of a given shock restricts the impulse response to be positive and let J
S1
be the index set of
variables for which identification restricts the impulse response to be negative. To impose the
additional identifying inequality sign restrictions beyond the zero restrictions of equation (3), we
solve
a D argmin
aD
Q
Aq
a 2
where the criterion function a is given by
a D
jεJ
S,C
3
kD0
f
r
ja
k
s
j
C
jεJ
S,
3
kD0
f
r
ja
k
s
j
Computationally, we implement this minimization using a simplex algorithm: it is available
on many statistical packages, such as MATLAB and RATS; for this paper we use the version
of the algorithm written in GAUSS by Bo Honore and Ekaterini Kyriazidou, available from
http://webware.princeton.edu/econometrics/programs/gaussmax/
Note that ‘zero’ restrictions, where the impulse responses of the jth variable to an impulse
vector a for, say, the first four periods are set to zero, can be incorporated into the analysis fairly
easily. These restrictions can be written as a restriction on the vector q that
0 D Rq 3
where R is a 4 ð m matrix of the form
R D
r
j1
0 ÐÐÐ r
jm
0
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
r
j1
3 ÐÐÐ r
jm
3
4
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
WHAT ARE THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY SHOCKS? 991
To identify an impulse matrix [a
1
,a
2
], where the first shock is a business cycle shock and
the second shock is a fiscal policy shock, first identify the business cycle shock a
1
D
Q
Aq
1
in
the manner described above and then identify the second shock a
2
by replacing the minimization
problem (2) with
a D argmin
aD
Q
Aq,RqD0,q
0
q
1
D0
a 5
i.e., by additionally imposing orthogonality to the first shock. The two restrictions Rq D 0,q
0
q
1
D
0 can jointly be written as
0 D
Q
Rq 6
where
Q
R
0
D [q
1
,R
0
]. Likewise, if orthogonality to two shocks the business cycle shock and the
monetary policy shockis required, identify the business cycle shock a
1
D
Q
Aq
1
and identify
the monetary policy shock a
2
D
Q
Aq
2
and solve
a D argmin
aD
Q
Aq,RqD0,q
0
q
1
,q
0
q
2
D0
a 7
Given the above we can now state our identification restrictions more formally. We only provide
two: the others follow the same pattern.
Definition 2 A business cycle shock impulse vector is an impulse vector a that minimizes a
criterion function a, which penalizes negative impulse responses of GDP, private consumption,
non-residential investment and government revenue at horizons k D 0,1,2,and3.
Definition 3 A basic government revenue shock impulse vector is an impulse vector a minimizing
a criterion function a, which penalizes negative impulse responses to the vector a of government
revenue at horizons k D 0, 1, 2, and 3.
The computations are performed using a Bayesian approach as in Uhlig (2005) (see also Sims
and Zha, 1998). We take a number of draws from the posterior. For each draw from the posterior
of the VAR coefficients and the variancecovariance matrix , the shocks are identified using the
criteria described above. Given the sample of draws for the impulse responses, confidence bands
can be plotted.
APPENDIX B: THE DATA
All the data we use are freely available from the World Wide Web. The data on components
of US national income is taken from the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA),
which are made publically available by the Bureau of Economic Analysis on their website
http://www.bea.gov/national/nipaweb/index.asp/. The monetary datathe interest rate, producer
commodity price index and adjusted reservesand the real wage data are taken from the Federal
Reserve Board of St Louis website http://www.stls.frb.org/fred/.
7.1. B.1. Definitions of Variables in the VAR
All the components of national income are in real per capita terms and are transformed from their
nominal values by dividing them by the gdp deflator (NIPA Table VII.1, row 4) and the population
Copyright 2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960 992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae
992 A. MOUNTFORD AND H. UHLIG
measure (NIPA Table II.1, row 35). The table and row numbers refer to the organization of the
data by the Bureau of Economic Analysis.
GDP: This is NIPA Table I.1, row 1.
Private Consumption: This is NIPA Table I.1, row 2.
Total Government Expenditure: This is ‘Federal Defense Consumption Expenditures’, NIPA
Table III.7 row 4, plus ‘Federal Non Defense Consumption Expenditures’, NIPA Table III.7,
row 15, plus ‘State and Local Consumption Expenditures’, NIPA Table III.7, row 28. plus
‘Federal Defense Gross Investment’, NIPA Table III.7, row 11, plus ‘Federal Non Defense Gross
Investment’, NIPA Table III.7, row 24, plus ‘State and Local Gross Investment’, NIPA Table III.7,
row 35.
Total Government Revenue:
11
This is ‘Total Government Receipts’, NIPA Table III.1, row 1,
minus ‘Net Transfers Payments’, NIPA Table III.1, row 8, and ‘Net Interest Paid’, NIPA Table III.1
row 11.
Real Wages: This is ‘Nonfarm Business Sector: Real Compensation Per Hour’ Series COMPRNFB
from the US Department of Labor: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Private Non-Residential Investment: This is ‘Nominal Gross Private Domestic Investment’,
NIPA Table I.1, row 6, minus private residential investment, NIPA Table I.1, row 11.
Interest Rate: This is the Federal Funds rate which is the series fedfunds at the Federal Reserve
Board of St Louis website http://www.stls.frb.org/fred/. We take the arithmetic average of the
monthly figures for the Federal Funds Rate.
Adjusted Reserves: This is the Adjusted Monetary Base given by the series adjressl at the Federal
Reserve Board of St Louis website http://www.stls.frb.org/fred/. We take the arithmetic average
of the monthly figures to get a quarterly figure.
PPIC: This is the Producer Price Index of Crude Materials given by the series ppicrm at the
Federal Reserve Board of St Louis website http://www.stls.frb.org/fred/. We take the arithmetic
average of the monthly figures to get a quarterly figure.
The GDP Deflator: This is NIPA Table VII.1, row 4.
The VAR system consists of these 10 variables at quarterly frequency from 1955 (Q1) to 2000
(Q4), has six lags, no constant or time trend, and uses the logarithm for all variables except the
interest rate where we have used the level.
The fiscal variables are chosen so that they will have different responses to business cycle
movements and fiscal policy shocks. The government expenditure variable is chosen so as to
exclude expenditures which will vary over the business cycle such as transfer payments; see,
for example, Blanchard (1997, p. 600) on this. The government receipts variable should clearly
respond positively to a business cycle shock; an increase in output should increase tax receipts
and reduce transfer payments.
11
This definition follows Blanchard and Perotti (2002) regarding transfer payments as negative taxes. We use this definition
in order not to obscure the implications of the new identification technique used in this paper, by using different data.
Copyright
2009 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. J. Appl. Econ. 24: 960992 (2009)
DOI: 10.1002/jae