Final report
Decentralisation
in Zambia
A comparative
analysis of strategies
and barriers to
implementation
Nava Ashraf
Oriana Bandiera
Florian Blum
November 2016
When citing this paper, please
use the title and the following
reference number:
S-41306-ZMB-1
Decentralisation in Zambia:
A Comparative Analysis of Strategies and Barriers to
Implementation
Florian Blum
Oriana Bandiera and Nava Ashraf
November 2016
ii
Contents
1. Introduction ....................................................................................................................... 1
1.1. Focus Country Summary .............................................................................................. 3
1.2. Decentralisation Reform Overview ............................................................................. 4
2. Analytical Approach .......................................................................................................... 7
3. Administrative Decentralisation ....................................................................................... 7
3.1. Risks in Devolving Policy Making Power ...................................................................... 8
3.2. Risks in Devolving HR Management ............................................................................ 9
3.3. Overcoming Limited Administrative Autonomy .......................................................... 9
3.4. Achieving Local Accountability after Administrative Decentralization ..................... 12
4. Fiscal Decentralisation ..................................................................................................... 13
4.1. Risks in Assigning Meaningful Expenditure Autonomy ............................................. 14
4.2. Risks in Local Revenue Collection .............................................................................. 14
4.3. Designing Transfer Systems ....................................................................................... 15
4.3.1. Transfer Systems in Focus Countries ................................................................. 17
4.3.2. Practical Challenges with Transfer Systems ....................................................... 17
4.4. Achieving Local Accountability after Fiscal Decentralization .................................... 18
5. Conclusion ........................................................................................................................ 19
6. Bibliography ..................................................................................................................... 20
7. Annex: Focus Country Comparison Based on the 10 Areas of the Zambian
Decentralisation Implementation Plan .................................................................................... 25
List of Tables
Table 1: Focus Country Overview ............................................................................................... 3
List of Figures
Figure 1: Ranking of Decentralization Reforms .......................................................................... 4
1
1. Introduction
Decentralisation reforms have been at the centre of the public policy agenda for multiple
decades. International institutions such as the World Bank embrace it as one of the major
governance reforms on their agenda. In addition, policymakers and researchers alike consider
decentralisation in China and India to be a determinant of their recent economic success
stories (Bardhan, 2002). The classical case in favour of decentralisation highlights the benefits
achieved through increased flexibility under localised decision-making while cautioning that
local decision makers might fail to internalize the externalities created through their decisions.
This notion, first formalized by Oates (1972), hence highlights that decentralisation is
beneficial when tastes are heterogeneous and there are no spillovers across jurisdictions.
In more recent theoretical work, this view has been extended to also incorporate transaction
and agency costs. Seabright (1996) argues that local governments have an informational
advantage over central governments as it is less costly for them to acquire information on
preferences and production costs. In addition, local governments might have stronger
incentives to make use of their superior information as they are more accountable to local
recipients of public services. Besley and Case (1995) suggest that increased accountability can
arise due to competition between local jurisdictions, because people can vote with their feet
and through yardstick competition.
Some caveats to this analysis exist. On the one hand, Bardhan and Mookherjee (2000) point
out that increased accountability of local decision-makers can backfire, as they might be more
prone to local elite capture. On the other hand, competition between local jurisdictions is
constrained by the presence of high moving costs and local specialisations in public good
provision.
Two additional key determinants of the success of decentralisation reforms exist. On the one
hand, as pointed out by Bardhan and Mookherjee (2000), the extent of fiscal autonomy given
to local governments determines the extent to which decentralisation reforms are prone to
elite capture. When local governments don’t only have power to determine expenditure
patterns but are also given tax collection power, the risk of elite capture is high. This is because
the ability to raise tax revenue not only allows captured decision-makers to redistribute funds
from all citizens to the capturing elites, but may also allow local elites to evade taxes such as
local property taxes. A reliance on user fees can reduce the extent of cross subsidization as
2
only public service recipients can be asked to contribute to the cost of the service. Yet, user
fees are often not feasible, for example when asking the recipients of the service to contribute
to its cost would defeat the purpose of the program. This could be the case for anti-poverty
programs aimed at redistributing income from rich to poor households, for example. An
alternative that also reduces the risk of elite capture is a reliance on grants from the central
government, which disconnects expenditure devolution from decentralisation in revenue
collection. While central government financing requires little administrative capacity at the
local level it also generates weak incentives for cost savings. When trying to maximize
production efficiency as part of a decentralisation reform, policymakers hence face a trade-
off between cost-minimization and the risk of elite capture.
The second key determinant of decentralisation success is the ability of local governments to
handle the assigned tasks. As has been pointed out by Bardhan (2002), disparities in technical
and administrative capacity between the central and the local governments are the main
cause of unsuccessful decentralisation reforms. The challenge with decentralisation reforms
is hence that central governments don’t know what to do and local governments don’t know
how to do it.
Given those countervailing theoretical arguments, the Zambian government has requested an
empirical investigation that evaluates the risks and opportunities associated with
decentralization. This paper reviews the literature on decentralization reforms in four Sub-
Saharan African countries (Tanzania, South Africa, Sierra Leone and Ethiopia) to understand
which factors can contribute to a successful decentralisation reform and how the design of
reforms affects their impact.
The four countries that this review focusses on were chosen because their context is
comparable to Zambia and they have experienced comprehensive decentralization reforms
which produced mixed results which maximises learning opportunities for Zambia. Today, all
countries have a de-jure system in which the administrative responsibility for health,
education and infrastructure has been devolved to local government’s authorities (LGAs). In
addition, LGAs in all focus countries have (limited) revenue raising and expenditure power.
3
1.1. Focus Country Summary
Table 1 provides summary information about the focus countries. In order to assess the
comparability of the focus countries to the Zambian context, it also benchmarks the
information to Zambia. The table puts a particular emphasis on the political structure of the
countries, as the literature considers this to be a major determinant of successful
decentralisation reforms.
The indicators highlight the dimensions that determine successful decentralization in which
the focus countries are comparable to Zambia. In particular, we focus on three dimensions:
Aggregate economic activity, the political system, and trade. First, in terms of aggregate
economic activity, column 2 in table 1 highlights that Zambia is comparable to Tanzania,
Ethiopia and Sierra Leone, whereas South Africa has a substantially higher GDP per capita.
South Africa also employs a higher fraction of GDP as government expenditure than the other
focus countries and Zambia. Column 3 shows that including South Africa is still important to
understand the Zambian context, as its democratic system is most comparable to Zambia. In
addition, column 4 highlights that, as opposed to Tanzania and Ethiopia, Sierra Leone, Zambia
and South Africa are all export based economies. As such, depending on the dimension of
interest, all focus countries provide relevant comparisons to Zambia.
Table 1: Focus Country Overview
Country
GDP per
capita in PPP
US$ (2015)
EIU
Democracy
Index (scale
from 1 to 10,
US: 8.11)
Dominated
by single
party?
Merchandise
trade (% of
GDP-2015)
Tanzania
2,667
5.77
Partially
35
Ethiopia
1,626
3.72
Yes
37
Sierra Leone
1,591
4.56
No
49
South Africa
13,165
7.82
Yes
60
Zambia
3,853
6.39
No
73
Sources: GDP per capita and trade figures-World Bank World Development Indicators; Government expenditure figures International
Monetary Fund; Democracy Index Economist Intelligence Unit
4
1.2. Decentralisation Reform Overview
In all four countries decentralization reforms shared three characteristics. First, similar to the
Zambian decentralisation plans, reforms in the focus countries involved the devolution of
basic service delivery powers to local governments. Second, in all cases the central
government retains authority over policy and standard setting in order to assure a minimum
quality level of public service delivery. Finally, while all focus countries allocate some revenue
collection power to local governments, financing of LGA activities primarily occurs through
central government grants.
Decentralisation reforms in the focus countries had various levels of effectiveness. Figure 1
presents a proposed ranking, with darker colours indicating more successful decentralization
reforms:
Figure 1: Ranking of Decentralization Reforms
Tanzania had the least effective experience. LGAs in Tanzania were established in 1982 and
have since then sequentially received increasing administrative power. The current local
government framework has been in place since 1996 and was comprehensively reformed in
1999. As part of this reform LGAs were assigned responsibility over basic service delivery
functions such as primary health and education, agricultural extension, local water supply and
road construction. Local government staffing and planning is still primarily controlled by the
central government, which is also the main provider of LGAs’ funds. Tanzania’s
decentralization efforts are widely considered to have been ineffective at best, and
destructive at worst. As the major decentralization reforms weren’t driven by a political will
to decentralize, but can be partially considered a response to external (donor) demand, its
ability to succeed was limited from the start. The main shortcoming of the Tanzanian
Tanzania
Sierra
Leone
South
Africa
Ethiopia
5
decentralization efforts is that the decentralization was never fully executed and instead
created breaks in the chain of command that now significantly limit service delivery. Local
governments rely on central government funding, capacity and structures to deliver public
services, yet there are no formal mechanisms that allows central government ministries and
local government agencies to cooperate (Fermet-Quinet et. al., 2008; Venugopal and Yilmaz,
2010).
In contrast to Tanzania, Sierra Leone embarked on a self-initiated decentralisation reform
after the end of the civil war in 2002 as a newly instated Truth and Reconciliation Commission
called for more locally inclusive policies. The main motivations for the decentralization reform
were to reconfigure political institutions to reduce risk of further sources of conflict and to
enhance government legitimacy and increase political support by taking power away from
local chieftains and strengthening LGAs. As part of this reform, Sierra Leone recreated the
institutions of local councils and formalised traditional chieftains, both of which had been
abolished in 1972. The government then proceeded to devolve administrative power over
primary and mid-secondary education, primary and secondary health facilities, roads,
agriculture, water and social welfare functions to the local institutions. This highlights a key
positive aspect of decentralization: In ethnically fractionalized states, such as Sierra Leone,
decentralization can work towards overcoming ethnic tensions as it provides autonomy to
communities that avoids sources of friction.
LGAs are primarily financed through a system of inter-governmental transfers.
Decentralization has, however, been slower then expected, with especially the
decentralisation of road construction still facing significant political constraints due to an
unwillingness of the central government to limit its authority. Given those constraints, the
evaluation of Sierra Leone’s decentralisation efforts is generally mixed. In particular, existing
evidence finds no effect of decentralisation on health care coverage and education indicators.
In addition, staff attendance in health and education facilities has decreased post-
decentralisation, possibly due to a lack of capacity to monitor attendance in the LGAs
(Edwards, Yilmaz & Boex, 2015; Srivastava and Larizza, 2011).
6
Decentralization in South Africa was initiated as a response to challenges after the end of
Apartheid and was needed to reincorporate the former homelands (‘bantustans’) in the
country. Decentralisation was finalised as part of the post-Apartheid constitution, passed in
1996, which allocated social service provision powers to LGAs while allowing the central
government to assist through coordination and policy making. A particular characteristic of
the South African decentralisation process is that it devolved decision making power to two
different sub-national layers of government. On the one hand, provincial governments are
responsible for the administration of major social services such as education and health.
Districts councils, on the other hand, organise infrastructure related service provision, such as
water, sewerage and electricity provision. While there is some evidence that the devolution
of power in South Africa has improved the targeting of HIV treatment expenditure to areas
most affected, strong influence from the ruling African National Congress limits de-facto local
autonomy and therefore LGAs’ ability to tailor public services to local needs (Wittenberg,
2003).
Finally, the literature widely considers the Ethiopian decentralisation attempt a successful
reform (e.g. Halvorsen, Smith and Shenkut, 2005). Decentralisation in Ethiopia started after
the end of socialist rule in 1991. The process was primarily driven by the Ethiopian People’s
Revolutionary Democratic Front
1
which aimed to reverse previous policies of homogenisation,
in order to assuage regions and ethnic groups demanding increased control and participation
(Cohen, 1995; Turton, 2006). The reform was completed in 1995 with the passing of a new
constitution that recognized the local right to self-determination and created a federal
structure. As part of the constitutional reform, LGAs were given full responsibility over basic
service delivery functions, including primary education, agriculture, health, water, sanitation,
roads. Similar to the reforms in the other focus countries the federal government retains
authority over setting policies and standards in the devolved administrative areas. Given
positive experience with the constitutional reform, decentralisation was extended in 2002
when a subset of decision powers was devolved further from regional states to local level
districts (“Woredas”). Local service delivery is primarily funded through (ear-marked) block
grants from the central government. Evaluations of Ethiopia’s decentralisation experience
1
The EPRDF is the ruling party in Ethiopia that was formed out of a coalition of militias that overthrew the
military junta in 1991.
7
point to decentralisation having improved the performance of the public sector, both through
increased efficiency in the use of resources and enhancing the outreach of public service
delivery.
2
As an explanation for this success the literature primarily points towards the
existence of strong party ties between local and central government officials that facilitate the
flow of information and generate strong incentives for local officials to enhance service
delivery (e.g. Khan et. al., 2014b).
2. Analytical Approach
The structure of this literature review is based on the methodology developed in Yilmaz, Beris
and Serrano-Berthet (2008). The main premise of this framework is that successful
decentralisation can only be achieved if it sustainably implements and enforces local
discretion and local accountability. The idea behind this premise is that local governments
need the autonomy, means and incentives to respond to citizens’ demands. At the same time,
citizens require the ability and opportunity to demand accountability from their LGA
representatives. We apply this framework to the focus countries in order to identify the
characteristics of decentralisation reforms that determine their success. We perform the
analysis of the literature separately for administrative and fiscal decentralization, focussing
first on the determinants of administrative autonomy and accountability before turning to
fiscal autonomy and accountability.
3. Administrative Decentralisation
The framework developed by Yilmaz, Beris and Serrano-Berthet (2008) identifies a number of
factors that determine the extent to which LGAs have de-facto autonomy over administrative
issues. This section will focus on a subset of two factors: First, local governments need to have
the de-jure and de-factor power to design and implement local policies. Second, the central
government needs to devolve HR management functions to LGAs. The following section will
discuss challenges with administrative autonomy separately for those two areas.
2
For example, a $1-dollar increase in decentralised expenditure is associated with a 3.7% increase in
educational enrolment rates (Khan et. al. 2014a).
8
3.1. Risks in Devolving Policy Making Power
Challenges with decentralisation reforms can be traced back to shortcomings in the allocation
of autonomy to LGAs to design and implement local policies. In general, the design of
decentralization reforms in focus countries either formally or informally restricts local
government autonomy, therefore limiting LGAs’ ability to use superior information to target
public expenditure and public service provision. In Sierra Leone, for example, devolution of
policy making power is undermined by a “divide and rule” strategy employed by the central
government to keep local councils weaker than they could be. This strategy allows the central
government to control LGAs by playing off traditional authorities (“chieftaincies”) against local
authorities. The resulting vacuum of power is facilitated through the design of the
decentralisation reform, which remained vague about the formal division of power between
LGAs and chieftaincies. This ambiguity is supported through a 2010 amendment of the
decentralisation reform in which the national government established a “district officer”
position at the local level that provides a direct link between national government and
chieftains, therefore bypassing LGAs and undermining the power of local councils (Srivastava
and Larizza, 2011).
A similar situation has been documented for South Africa, where competencies are more
dispersed at the local level. In particular, responsibilities are spread over three layers of local
government: provincial governments are responsible for the administration of major social
services (especially education and health), whereas infrastructure services are administered
by district level councils. Overlapping competencies create policy uncertainty that reduces
local autonomy. In addition, district councils have passed service delivery functions on to local
councils but maintain the responsibility for their financing. This division was initially born out
of the necessity to address administrative capacity gaps at the local council level but has
persisted even after the capacity had been built and now creates unnecessarily long chain of
commands (Wittenberg, 2003).
While local administrative autonomy is limited through mostly informal channels for Sierra
Leone and South Africa, a number of authors suggest that the major risk to decentralization
in Ethiopia originates in the formal channels developed by the central government (Yilmaz and
9
Venugopal, 2011). In particular, strong central party influence significantly restricts local
autonomy, as local government officials are incentivized by and accountable to the (central)
party administration. The performance of local level development agents, for example, is
primarily measured through the achievement of planning targets set centrally by the party
(Dom and Mussa, 2006). Taken together, this experience therefore suggests that
understanding the motivations of central government decision makers, and making sure that
central stakeholders are committed to devolving power to the local level, is crucial.
3.2. Risks in Devolving HR Management
Similar to the devolution of power to design and implement local policies, the decentralisation
of staffing decisions is also limited in the focus countries. In Tanzania, for example, all district
level operations are overseen and managed by the District Executive Director (“DED”) who is
appointed by the central government. The DED can himself appoint the executives of lower
level LGAs, leaving no space for local decision making in appointing executives. This pattern
of central influence also exists for non-executive positions. Tanzania’s LGA staffing decisions
are made by local employment boards, which have 3 members from the central and 2
members from the local governments, therefore limiting local staffing autonomy. Similarly,
doctors, secondary school teachers, accountants, nurses and agricultural extension officers
are typically recruited by the responsible central ministry and then deployed to LGAs
(Venugopal and Yilmaz, 2010).
A similar situation exists in Ethiopia, where all local hiring and firing decisions require approval
from higher levels of government. For example, regional bureaucrats need to approve hiring
decisions for teachers and zonal as well as regional executives have the ability to overrule
woreda level hiring decisions. Similarly, the EPRDF retains a decisive role in the appointment
of high-level executives at the local levels (Yilmaz and Venugopal, 2011).
3.3. Overcoming Limited Administrative Autonomy
A possible explanation for de-facto low levels of administrative autonomy is the prevalence of
capacity constraints at the local level. Experience from the focus countries shows that
especially skills necessary for budget execution, such as planning and accounting skills, as well
10
as financial and HR management skills, are in short supply at the local level. For example, an
assessment of LGA performance in Tanzania shows that only 8.6% of councils have high
financial management capabilities, with most rural councils receiving the lowest possible
rating (World Bank, 2001). A more recent assessment reveals that while the situation has
improved for some LGA’s, particularly those close to urban areas and the capital city,
inadequacies of key professional staff with some of the above skills, such as accountants,
continue to persist, particularly in rural councils (Parliamentary Centre, 2011).
In addition, LGAs are constrained by insufficient management skills. For the case of South
Africa, limited staffing ability of local governments especially for elected positions led to
inadequate staff establishments (Koelble & Siddle, 2012). This did not only result in a high rate
of vacancies in local governments but also led LGAs to install non-elected bureaucrats in
leading (political) LGA position, therefore undermining local accountability (Wittenberg,
2003). Similarly, Sierra Leone has experimented with decentralized recruitment of staff but
has resumed central recruitment after it was found that the skill sets of the newly recruited
staff were far below those of (local) staff assigned by the (central) Office of the Establishment
Secretary (Kanu, 2009).
Countries have experimented with multiple ways of overcoming human capacity constraints.
First, development partners in Tanzania provided computerised systems for accounting,
planning, M&E and budget reporting as part of the decentralization reform. Donors also
supported the hiring of technical advisors who are tasked with supplementing a lack of
administrative capacity at the local government level. While there exists no evaluation for this
program, anecdotal evidence suggests that while this program was effective in providing the
necessary infrastructure for decentralization, it did not allow LGAs to satisfactorily fulfil their
duties in the long run (Frumence et. al., 2013).
A second capacity building measure regularly employed by central governments involves the
provision of training to local government staff. This is either organized through capacity
building grants allocated to LGAs or through standardized countrywide training provisions.
The evidence on such programs is generally positive. Tanzania has so far invested a total of 6
billion Tanzanian Shillings (approx. 3 million USD) in capacity building grants, mostly targeted
at improving planning and financial management skills. The literature perceives this program
11
to have been successful in improving the level and targeting of service delivery (REPOA, 2008).
Similarly, the Ethiopian central government maintains training programs for elected LGA
officials that focus on agricultural development, basic management, financial management,
integrated rural development and ethics and are generally reviewed positively (Beyene, 2000).
The South African government undertook a special capacity building measure to train LGA
staff on effective public service provision. As part of this program, LGAs cooperated with
private companies tasked with training LGA personnel in the area of water management. This
measure has been evaluated very positively as it generated local government capacity and
also supported emerging companies in the area of water management (Elhiraika, 2007).
Finally, all focus countries have also experimented with transferring experienced central
government staff to LGAs in order to fill capacity gaps. While this is generally viewed as an
effective measure to overcome human capital constraints, central government staff is
typically unfamiliar with local conditions. This program therefore reduces LGAs’ ability to
target its services to local demand conditions.
While capacity building attempts are generally viewed favourably in the literature, two major
challenges have arisen. First, when wages for LGA staff are fixed between locations, qualified
staff tends to sort into urban or more developed areas, leading to disadvantages for poorer
regions. It is hence key to devolve de facto autonomy over staff compensation to local
councils, and assure that financing for compensation is readily available (see also section on
financial decentralization below). Second, LGAs don’t only compete with each other but also
with the private sector, given that especially budget execution skills are also crucial for the
success of businesses. As such, attrition, especially after capacity building programs have been
completed, is a major concern (Girishankar et. al., 2006). The economic literature highlights a
number of ways that retention of government workers can be assured. First, increased
compensation and performance pay can foster retention (e.g. Deserranno, 2016; Dal Bo et. al.
2013). In addition, opportunities for career development, continuing education, , resource
availability and recognition/appreciation have been shown to reduce health worker attrition
in various developing country contexts (see the literature review by Willis-Shattuck et. al.,
2008).
12
3.4. Achieving Local Accountability after Administrative
Decentralization
When considering the determinants of local accountability, Yilmaz, Beris and Serrano-Berthet
(2008) separate public and social accountability. In their terminology, public accountability
refers to the accountability of leading administrators at the local level to their top
administrative officers or auditors. Social accountability, on the other hand, refers to
community-based auditing of the quality of service provision.
Focus countries’ experiences with public accountability are mixed. On the one hand, high
levels of public accountability are a possible explanation for the positive performance of South
Africa’s and Ethiopia’s decentralization reform. To overcome communication challenges, the
South African central government has established sector specific intergovernmental relations
committees of ministers and members of provincial councils. While such committees are only
consultative with limited executive powers, they can still provide incentives for service
providers to increase accountability and enhance information flows (Eaton, Kaiser and Smoke,
2010). Similarly, public accountability in Ethiopia is driven by strong incentives provided by
the centralised party structure that makes career progression of civil-servants dependent on
service delivery outcomes (World Bank, 2005; Yilmaz and Venugopal, 2011).
While accountability in Ethiopia works for service providers, it works significantly less for local
councillors tasked with overseeing executive policy implementation and service delivery. As
they are partially accountable to higher level (party) bureaucracies and partially to local
electorates, the aforementioned incentive channel is weakened, therefore undermining
public accountability (Khan et. al., 2014a). A similar picture emerges for Tanzania where all of
the executive staff is centrally appointed but monitored by local level councils. As local
councils have no instruments to discipline centrally appointed staff and there are no formal
linkages that allow the central government to effectively monitor local level executives, an
agency problem arises. This set-up therefore generates weak incentives for service providers
which undermines the effectiveness of decentralisation reforms (Venugopal and Yilmaz,
2010).
Achieving social accountability has proven to be significantly more difficult than achieving
public accountability in the focus countries as there is little evidence of local citizens
effectively sanctioning poorly performing local government officials. In Tanzania, for example,
13
the standard method to assure social accountability is through village assembly meetings.
While this assembly has the de-facto authority to overrule village leaders’ decisions,
Venugopal and Yilmaz (2010) report that there are no examples of such behaviour. At the
same time, village assemblies are not equipped with the authority to sanction local council
members, therefore limiting opportunities for social accountability.
A success story supporting the effectiveness of social accountability mechanisms comes from
Ethiopia, where structured feedback sessions that brought together citizens and service
providers significantly strengthened citizen participation and improved service delivery
outcomes. Similarly, grievance redress mechanisms through a designated ombudsman,
formalised citizen feedback mechanisms and joint service improvement plans led to
improvements in basic service provision (Khan et. al., 2014b). However, Ethiopia’s strong party
leadership, one of the drivers of successful public accountability, also undermines more
traditional social accountability channels. Traditionally, village level assembly (“kebele”)
meetings used to be the first point of contact for citizens to provide feedback about service
provision. In the recent past, it has however been argued that kebeles have come to be
primarily controlled by party cadres, and are hence unable to act as a platform that supports
social accountability (Pausewang et. al., 2002; Human Rights Watch, 2010).
4. Fiscal Decentralisation
The framework developed by Yilmaz, Beris and Serrano-Berthet (2008) identifies three factors
that determine the extent to which LGAs have de-facto autonomy over fiscal issues. First, LGAs
require a meaningful level of expenditure responsibility. For LGAs to be able to respond to
local needs, it is crucial that they retain discretion to make their own expenditure allocation
decisions. Second, LGAs need to have the autonomy and capacity to collect their own revenue.
LGAs should have rate-setting authority over locally assigned revenues and should be allowed
to define their own tax base. This argument is associated with the notion that local
governments are more accountable when relying on their own tax bases (Faguet, 2008).
Finally, LGAs need to receive financing assistance through transfers. This is because own-tax
revenue typically isn’t sufficient to cover LGAs expenditure requirements. To bridge this gap,
local authorities rely on transfers from the central government. Maintaining autonomy and
accountability in the design of this transfer system has proven to be a major challenge in focus
countries.
14
4.1. Risks in Assigning Meaningful Expenditure Autonomy
Expenditure autonomy is typically limited by central regulation. In particular, experiences
from the focus countries show that the de-facto expenditure autonomy allocated to local
governments differs substantially from the de-jure status. In Tanzania, for example, while
LGAs have de-jure autonomy over expenditure allocation, 78.5% of local government
spending is recurrent, mostly due to high staff costs, leave little space for decentralised
expenditure targeting.
Expenditure autonomy is mostly undermined through the employed financing mechanisms
and, among those, primarily through the reliance of LGAs on central government transfers.
With the aim of increasing effectiveness, such transfers are typically earmarked or are
associated with prescribed sector-specific maximum spending. In Tanzania, for example, LGAs
have the de-jure autonomy to determine the wage structure for their employees
independently. Yet, spending limits on wages, together with a transfer allocation that is
dependent on the number of LGA employees, typically prescribes a specific level set by the
central government (World Bank, 2001).
A similar picture emerges for the case of South Africa, where LGAs are responsible for
financing the salary of staff at the local level through unconditional grants received from the
central government. While this set-up allocates a high de-jure autonomy to local
governments, central regulation de-facto limits local discretion by describing salary levels for
local staff and making transfer allocation conditional on the expected wage bill, leaving little
space for discretionary budget allocation (Wittenberg, 2003).
4.2. Risks in Local Revenue Collection
The framework developed by Yilmaz, Beris and Serrano-Berthet (2008) suggests that the
ability of local level governments to finance their operations through own revenue sources is
a crucial determinant of LGA autonomy. Experience from focus countries does, however,
reveal three challenges with local revenue collection.
First, levels of locally collected revenue are generally low. For example, while Sierra Leone’s
LGAs finance 25% to 30% of their total expenditure through self-collected revenue, Tanzanian
LGAs only achieve a mere 6.9% (USAID, 2010; Searle, 2009). This is driven by the fact that in
the absence of transfers only narrow tax bases can be put under the control of local
governments as the taxation of large tax bases, such as corporate profit, generates spillovers
15
between LGAs that aren’t internalized under a decentralized system. In addition, devolution
of income and corporate tax bases significantly exacerbate the inequality between urban and
rural LGAs. Given those constraints, only narrow tax bases, such as property value, are
typically delegated to local governments. Those bases, however, are too narrow to finance
the recurrent expenditure of especially rural LGAs (Oates, 1972).
Second, local revenue collection can exacerbate political tension and undermine social
accountability. On the one hand, even the devolution of narrow tax bases, such as property
value, is likely to generate significant inequality in tax collection rates between urban and rural
areas and hence supports differential service provision levels in the absence of transfers. On
the other hand, local revenue collection makes LGAs prone to elite capture. In Sierra Leone,
for example, anecdotal evidence suggests that the devolution of property tax collection power
significantly increased pressure from (property owning) local elites to reduce tax collection
efforts, therefore undermining local fiscal capacity (Jibao and Prichard, 2013).
Third, fiscal capacity is not only undermined by local elites but also through the incentives
created by fiscal transfer mechanisms. In Ethiopia, for example, Woredas receive targets for
tax collection but are responsible to transfer any excess tax collected back to the regional
level. As this arrangement significantly reduces Woredas’ benefits from tax collection, it
generates limited incentives to create tax collection capacity at the local level (Adal et. al.,
2005).
4.3. Designing Transfer Systems
Establishing a fiscal transfer system to finance LGA expenditure is a central part of any
decentralisation reform. On the one hand, transfers are suitable mechanisms to redistribute
income between rich (urban) and poor (rural) areas in order to equalize levels of public service
provision (e.g. Bordignon, Manasse and Tabellini, 2001). Transfers can also be used to
internalize inter-regional spillovers. For example, LGAs might be more likely to invest in
infrastructure that also benefits other regions (for example building power plants that serve
multiple regions) if inter-regional transfers assure that they are compensated for the resulting
benefits. Finally, transfers can also act as an insurance against local economic shocks, for
example allowing LGAs to raise government expenditure in response to high local
unemployment (e.g. Lockwood, 1999).
16
Designing intergovernmental transfer systems is, however, significantly constrained by inter-
regional heterogeneity and information asymmetries between the central and local
government (Bordignon, Manasse and Tabellini, 2001). For example, there might be spatially
diverging preferences for different public goods (Cremer et. al., 1996). Alternatively, localized
access to technologies used for the production of public goods can lead to differences in cost
structures (Cornes and Silva, 2000). When those differences aren’t directly observable by the
central government they can lead regions with lower costs for public good production to
receive higher transfers than they require, leaving high cost regions short of funding. Similarly,
central government transfers can also weaken LGAs’ incentive structure, for example by
reducing effort exerted on local revenue collection.
When designing transfer systems, policy makers therefore need to assure that they maintain
local incentives for revenue collection and efficient public good production while also basing
transfer allocations on indicators that are proportional to preferences for public goods and
cost measures. One example used in the literature for such an indicator is the income or
property tax rate chosen by the local government: Higher tax rates are costly but imply a
higher valuation for tax revenue which is used to signal a region with higher demand for public
goods or higher costs. Regions with higher tax rates should therefore be rewarded with higher
transfers (Bordignon, Manasse and Tabellini, 2001).
In reality, best practice suggests using one of two possible options to design transfer systems.
On the one hand, the amount of transfers can be based on a “normative” measure of the costs
associated with public service delivery. Examples that have been used include local population
size and estimates of the costs associated with public good production. This option is primarily
used by developed countries where reliable accounting data is available. For example, most
OECD countries use fixed distribution formulas that reflect the average or normative cost of
the basic package of public services provided by LGAs. It is, however, unclear to what extent
such measures can be obtained in a developing country context (Bergvall et. al., 2006).
On the other hand, transfer amounts can be based on measures of tax collection effort. Recent
developing country experience suggests that tying transfer formulas to revenue generation
can serve as a motivator for subnational governments to embark on wealth enhancing
policies. The challenge is to identify measures of tax collection effort that are independent of
local conditions to not further exacerbate inequality between rural and urban areas. Potential
17
measures include effective tax rates and tax collection relative to an independent assessment
of the tax base size (Poeschl and Weingast, 2013).
4.3.1. Transfer Systems in Focus Countries
Transfer systems in the focus countries typically take one of two possible shapes. On the one
hand, they can be indicator-based, meaning that the size of central government transfers is
determined by LGA-specific characteristics, such as the local development indices or poverty
and literacy rates. A key challenge with this approach is that fund allocation is unrelated to
costs. Similarly, indicator-based approaches are typically biased towards relatively large and
poor LGAs. Taken together, an indicator-based approach typically leaves richer LGAs with high
costs short of financing. In addition, this approach requires regularly updated information on
development indicators collected at the local government level, which is costly in itself.
An alternative to the indicator-based approach used in the focus countries is a cost-based
approach to transfer allocation, which determines transfer size as a function of LGA
administration costs. While the cost based-approach is certain to recover LGA expenditure,
experience from Sub-Saharan African countries shows that it can lead to blowing up of staff,
or breaking down of LGA units to increase transfer allocation (Smoke, 2003 and 2008).
4.3.2. Practical Challenges with Transfer Systems
Experience from the focus countries shows that the disparity between rich (urban) and poor
(rural) LGAs is a key challenge to effective transfer systems design. In South Africa, for
example, LGAs’ share of transfer income spans from 15% in urban areas to 80% in more rural
LGAs. Urban municipalities are therefore able to achieve the same level of service delivery as
rural regions while maintaining a higher independence from the central government, which
creates significant spatial heterogeneity in local autonomy and the effectiveness of
decentralisation reforms (Koelble & Siddle, 2012).
A second challenge that has arisen in focus countries relates to the timeliness and reliability
of transfer payments. In Sierra Leone, for example, the central government demands detailed
documentation and justifications of previous expenditure before approving additional
payments. As the assessment of such reports is time consuming, this system causes
substantial uncertainty, which has shown to particularly delay infrastructure investments
(Edwards, Yilmaz and Boex, 2015).
18
Finally, the central government in South Africa regularly engages in large discretionary
investments in areas allocated to local governments, such as road construction. As
coordination between LGAs and the central government is insufficient, such investments
regularly conflict with LGA budgeting, therefore not only reducing local government
autonomy but also leading to inefficient resource allocation (Wittenberg, 2003).
4.4. Achieving Local Accountability after Fiscal Decentralization
Similar to administrative decentralisation, Yilmaz, Beris and Serrano-Berthet (2008) separate
public and social accountability when considering the determinants of local accountability in
the fiscal sphere. In their terminology, public accountability refers to the implementation of
effective, transparent and rule based public financial management. Social accountability, on
the other hand, refers to community-based monitoring of financial management, for example
through legislators, the civil society or the general public.
While focus countries have actively attempted to improve public accountability, those efforts
have been met with a number of challenges. On the one hand, implementing consistent
budgeting procedures and public financial management structures requires human capacity
at the local level. Experience from the focus countries shows that especially skills necessary
for budget execution, such as planning and accounting skills, as well as financial management,
are typically in short supply in local government authorities. In addition, reports on Ethiopia
and Tanzania suggest that there is a lack of capacity to monitor local expenditure. As a result
of such human capacity constraints, LGAs require assistance by experts from higher levels of
governments, therefore undermining local autonomy and reducing the effectiveness of
decentralisation reforms. On the other hand, evidence from Ethiopia suggests that elected
representatives tend to have lower levels of literacy rates compared to full time civils servants.
This significantly constraints their ability to oversee the planning, budgeting and service
delivery process and therefore reduces public accountability (Yilmaz and Venugopal, 2009).
Social accountability faces a similar challenge, as it is unclear whether legislators, the civil
society and the general public have access to the necessary information to scrutinize public
financial management. Evidence from Tanzania suggests that citizens are typically uninformed
about the decision power available to LGAs, let alone their performance (World Bank, 2010).
Similarly, recent survey evidence from Ethiopia shows that 91% of respondents are unaware
of the extent of financial autonomy allocated to their local government. A similar fraction was
19
unaware of how local expenditure was allocated (FTAPS, 2009). Taken together, this evidence
suggests that local social accountability is significantly constrained by information
asymmetries, hinting to the importance of LGA transparency during and after the
decentralisation process.
5. Conclusion
Decentralisation reforms are typically used as a policy instrument to improve the targeting of
public services and the accountability of public service providers, thereby enhancing the
effectiveness of public sector operations as a whole. This article has argued that there exists
substantial heterogeneity in the extent to which decentralisation reforms allocate de-facto
autonomy to local governments, driven primarily by the design of the reform process.
Evidence from South Africa, Tanzania, Ethiopia and Sierra Leone suggests that decentralisation
reforms maintain strong elements of central regulation and therefore remain incomplete.
Taken together, experience from the focus countries suggests that assuring a commitment to
delegating power at the central level and the availability of capacity to deliver services and
demand accountability at the local level is key for successful decentralisation.
20
6. Bibliography
Adal, Y., Wube, N., & Cherinet, H. (2005). “Study on the implementation of decentralization
policy in ethiopia.“ Addis Ababa: Oxfam.
Bardhan, P. (2002). “Decentralization of governance and development”. The journal of
economic perspectives, 16(4), 185-205.
Bergvall, D., Charbit, C., Kraan, D. J., & Merk, O. (2006). “Intergovernmental transfers and
decentralised public spending.“ OECD Journal on Budgeting, 5(4), 111.
Beyene, Asmelash. (2000). “Decentralization as a tool for Resolving the Nationality Problem:
the Ethiopian Experience”. Regional Development Dialogue 21(2): 122147.
Bordignon, M., Manasse, P., & Tabellini, G. (2001). “Optimal regional redistribution under
asymmetric information.“ The American Economic Review, 91(3), 709-723.
Cohen, J. M. (1995). “Capacity building in the public sector: a focused framework for analysis
and action”. International Review of Administrative Sciences, 61(3), 407-422.
Cornes, R. C., & Silva, E. C. (2000). “Local public goods, risk sharing, and private information
in federal systems.“ Journal of Urban Economics, 47(1), 39-60.
Cremer, J., Estache, A. and Seabright, P. (1996). “Decentralizing public services: what can we
learn from the theory of the firm?” Revue d’Economie Politique, 106: 3760.
Dom, Catherine, and Mohammed Mussa. (2006). Review of implementation of the
decentralisation policy: A sample survey in six weredas of Amhara Region. Report for the
Embassy of Sweden and Amhara National Regional State. Oxford, UK
21
Edwards, Benjamin, Serdar Yilmaz, and Jamie Boex. (2015) "Decentralization as a Post
Conflict Strategy: Local Government Discretion and Accountability in Sierra Leone." Public
Administration and Development 35.1: 46-60.
Elhiraika, A. B. (2007). “Fiscal decentralization and public service delivery in South Africa.“
African Trade Policy Centre (58).
Faguet, J. P. (2014). “Decentralization and governance”. World Development, 53, 2-13.
Faguet, J. P. (2008). “Decentralisation's effects on public investment: evidence and policy
lessons from Bolivia and Colombia.” The Journal of Development Studies, 44(8), 1100-1121.
Fermet-Quinet, Eric, Fatoumata Samake, Yumiko Sakurai. (2008). “PVS Evaluation Report.”
OiE Report 20112008.
Frumence, G., Nyamhanga, T., Mwangu, M., & Hurtig, A. K. (2013). “Challenges to the
implementation of health sector decentralization in Tanzania: experiences from Kongwa
district council. “ Global health action, 6.
Girishankar, N., Degroot, D., & Pillay, T. V. (2006). “Measuring Intergovernmental Fiscal
Performance in South Afirca: Issues in Municipal Grant Monitoring.“ World bank.
Halvorsen Tor and Robert L. Smith. (2005). “Delivery of Health and Education Services in
Ethiopia: The Role of National Institutions.” Presentation at the 8th Annual Norwegian
Education Trust Fund Seminar. October 13th and 14th. Oslo, Norway.
22
Human Rights Watch, 2010. ““One Hundred Ways of Putting Pressure- Violations of Freedom
of Expression and Association in Ethiopia.” Human Rights Watch: New York.
Kanu, Alhassan. (2009). “Administrative Decentralization: Building the Non-Financial
Capacity of Local Governments” in Yongmei Zhou (ed.) Decentralization, Democracy, and
development Recent Experience from Sierra Leone. World Bank: Washington DC.
Khan, Qaiser M., et al. (2014a). “Decentralization’s effect on education, health and
agriculture outcomes, and on distribution: Evidence from Ethiopia“. In first Annual Bank
Conference on Africa, Paris.
Khan, Qaiser M., et al. (2014b). “Improving basic services for the bottom forty percent:
lessons from Ethiopia.” World Bank Publications.
Koelble, T. A., & Siddle, A. (2014). “Institutional complexity and unanticipated consequences:
the failure of decentralization in South Africa.“ Democratization, 21(6), 1117-1133.
Lockwood, B. (1999). “Inter-regional insurance.“ Journal of Public Economics, 72(1), 1-37.
Oates, Wallace. (1972). “Fiscal Federalism”. New York: Harcourt Brace.
Parliamentary Centre. (2011). Local Government Budgeting and Implementation in
Tanzania.” Parliamentary Strengthening Program (APSP) for Budget Oversight.
Pausewang, S., Tronvoll, K., & Aalen, L. (2002). “Ethiopia since the Derg. A Decade of
Democratic Pretension and Performance. London/New York.
23
Poeschl, C., & Weingast, B. R. (2013). “The Fiscal Interest Approach: The Design of Tax and
Transfer Systems.“ Mimeo.
Raff, Horst, and Wilson, J. (1997). “Income Redistribution with Well-Informed Local
Governments.” International Tax and Public Finance 4, 407-427.
REPOA (2008). “Local Governance Finances and Service Delivery in Tanzania: A summary of
findings from six councils.” REPOA Working Paper, Dar Es Salaam.
Searle, B. (2009). “Sierra Leone: Issues in Fiscal Decentralization.“ World Bank, AFTPR,
Washington, DC.
Smoke, P. (2003). “Decentralisation in Africa: goals, dimensions, myths and challenges.“
Public administration and Development, 23(1), 7-16.
Smoke, P. (2008). “The evolution of subnational development planning under
decentralization reforms in Kenya and Uganda.“ Planning and Decentralization: Contested
Spaces for Public Action in the Global South, 89-105.
Srivastava, V., & Larizza, M. (2011). “Decentralization in postconflict Sierra Leone: the genie
is out of the bottle”. “Yes Africa Can: Success Stories from a Dynamic Continent”, 141-154.
Tiebout, Charles M. (1956). “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures.” Journal of Political
Economy 64, 416-424.
Turton, D. (Ed.). (2006). “Ethnic federalism: The Ethiopian experience in comparative
perspective“. James Currey.
24
USAID. (2010). “Comparative Assessment of Decentralization in Africa: Final Report and
Summary of Findings.” Washington, DC: USAID.
Venugopal, Varsha, and Serdar Yilmaz. (2010). "Decentralization in Tanzania: An assessment
of local government discretion and accountability." Public Administration and Development
30.3: 215-231.
Wittenberg, Martin. (2003). “Decentralisation in South Africa.” Econometric Research
Southern Africa.
World Bank. (2001). “The United Republic of Tanzania: Decentralisation Sector Work.”
Report 22048. World Bank, Africa Regional Office.
World Bank. (2005). “An Independent Review of World Bank Support to Capacity Building in
Africa: The Case of Ethiopia”.
Yilmaz, Serdar, Yakup Beris, and Rodrigo Serrano-Berthet. (2008). “Local government
discretion and accountability: A diagnostic framework for local governance.” World Bank.
Social development department.
Yilmaz, Serdar and Varsha Venugopal (2011). “Obstacles to Decentralization in Ethiopia:
Political Controls versus Discretion and Accountability.”
Jibao, S. S., & Prichard, W. (2013). “Rebuilding Local Government Finance After Conflict: The
political economy of property tax reform in post-conflict Sierra Leone.“ International Centre
for Tax and Development Working Paper, 12.
25
7. Annex: Focus Country Comparison Based on the 10 Areas of the Zambian
Decentralisation Implementation Plan
Country/
Category
Tanzania
South Africa
Sierra Leone
Ethiopia
Legal and
Regulatory
Reforms
Local Government Reforms I
(1982): Reinstitution of LGAs with
mainly administrative
responsibilities.
Local Government Reforms II
(2009): Increasing fiscal
decentralization.
Organized Local
Government Act (No.52,
1997): Reintroduction of
local authorities as part of
post-Apartheid
constitutional reform.
Local Government Act
(2004): Introduction of Local
Councils and devolution of
administrative
responsibilities.
National Decentralization
Policy (2010): Revision of
legislature and standards.
District Level Decentralization
Program: Phase I (1991)
devolution of administrative
responsibility from national to
regional level; Phase II (2002)
further devolution from regional
to district level.
Sector
Devolution
LGA Responsibility: Primary
education, primary and
preventive health, water supply,
sewerage and sanitation in rural
areas, solid waste, agricultural
extension
LGA Responsibility:
Electricity, water supply,
sewerage and sanitation,
firefighting, municipal
health services, land use,
municipal infrastructure,
food markets, recreational
areas, local tourism
LGA Responsibility: Primary
and secondary education &
health care, rural water
supply, sanitation, waste
management, agriculture,
youth services, social
assistance, and local
firefighting
LGA Responsibility:
School management, primary
and post-natal health care,
hospital/clinic administration,
primary schools, HIV/AIDS and
malaria prevention, water supply
Fiscal
Decentralisation
Share of expenditure financed
through own revenue:
6.9%
Fraction of conditional grants in
total financing:
40%
Fraction of total transfers
earmarked:
80%
Share of expenditure
financed through own
revenue:
52.5% (rural), 86% (urban)
Fraction of conditional
grants in total financing:
30%
Fraction of total transfers
earmarked:
100%
Share of expenditure
financed through own
revenue:
25%
Fraction of conditional
grants in total financing:
0%
Fraction of total transfers
earmarked:
100%
Share of expenditure financed
through own revenue:
20-30 %
Fraction of conditional grants in
total financing:
0%
Fraction of total transfers
earmarked:
91%
Sensitisation
and Civic
Education
-Government cooperates with
Radio Free Africa to inform
people about decentralization
-DDTP lead by UNDP for
“Deepening Democracy”
-The Local Government
Negotiating Forum ran
Workshops and hosted
forums to educate and
garner support for the
1997 Decentralization
Two progammess led by civil
defense forces:
Disarmament, Reintegration
and Reconciliation (political
education and economic
integration) and Civic
Education (civing and human
rights education)
-Ruling party offers courses for
civic education
-“Promoting Basic Services
Program” implemented by the
CG to educate the public to
participate in local governance
26
Auditing and
Monitoring
-Monthly Internal performance
audits
-External audits as support and
for donor-funded or development
projects
- Annual
Intergovernmental Fiscal
Reviews (IGFR)
-Non-Central Monitoring
by Mayoral Executive
Committee
-Introduction of Audit Service
Sierra Leone (ASSL) in 1998
- Specialised agency to
conduct regular LGA audits
-Internal Audit and Investigations
Group (IAIG), run by UNOPS
Capacity
Building
-University Courses for LGA
officials
-Donor and private company
support
- Central government grants for
capacity building conditional on
basic financial management and
transparency requirements
-Institutional capacity
building grant (7.5% of
unconditional grants) for
poor municipalities
-Human Capital
Programme by the ADB to
improve financial
management and service
delivery
-World Bank Institutional
Reform and Capacity Building
(IRCBP) Project
-Multi-Donor Budget Support
(MDBS) to assess
implementation of donor-
funded development
projects
-National Capacity Building
Program (NCBP) targets a broad
range of 14 sectors
-Central-Government-run
training programs for elected
district-level officials
Local
Accountability
and Governance
-Limited formal local
accountability measures
-Lack of Accountability due to
limited ability of community to
participate, primarily as a result of
insufficient
information/transparency and
low education
-Approximately a third of
municipalities have formal
community participation
mechanisms, primarily
through community
forums
-Lack of accountability by
centrally-deployed staff
-Local conflict between LGAs
and chiefdoms limits
accountability
-Regional targets overrule
community needs
- Strong central party influence
-Decision-making compromised
byintergovernmental
distribution system
Local
Development
Planning and
Budgeting
-Limited local development-
planning efforts due to central
government prescriptions and
partial intervention
-Local Development
Planning constrained by
discretionary central
spending
-Establishment of
communications channel
through which local
communities can indicate
their needs to central
government (through
nonpartisan Financial and
Fiscal Commission (FFC))
-Innovation: New
budgeting framework that
allows multi-year
budgeting for LGAs.
-Councils have dedicated
positions for internal
auditors and m&e officers
-Sufficient staff to carry out
planning, budgeting, and
accounting available at the
local level
-Uncertainty over division of
responsibilities limits
development planning
-Limited room for discretionary
capital budgeting, as 91% is
earmarked for administrative
and operational expenditures
27
Financial
Management
and
Accounting
-Low capacity, which requires
(external or central government)
technical advisors to be hired as
the backbone of day-to-day
operations
-Audit Reports indicate recent
improvements in financial
management
-Weak Financial
Management with 27
Billion Rand over-
expenditure on items
unrelated to service
delivery
-Missing formal taxation
by-laws in most
municipalities
-Central government
requirement to receive LGA
expenditure report before
issuing new funds delays
public service delivery
-High Intransparency in
Financial Management due
to delays in publication of
accounting reports
-Limited information on
accounting procedures and the
reliability of provided
information.
Infrastructure
Development
-Local Government Transport
Programme (LGTP) and Village
Travel and Transport Programme
(VTTP): Both require LGAs to
independently plan and tender
their transport development
-Municipal Infrastructure
Grant (MIG) for
Infrastructure
development at the
municipal level
-Devolution of infrastructure
(especially road) planning
delayed due to political
confrontations
-No identifiable local
initiatives for Infrastructure
development yet
-Telephone infrastructure
decisions are made by local
entities
Designed by soapbox.co.uk
The International Growth Centre
(IGC) aims to promote sustainable
growth in developing countries
by providing demand-led policy
advicebased on frontier research.
Find out more about
ourworkonourwebsite
www.theigc.org
For media or communications
enquiries, please contact
Subscribe to our newsletter
and topicupdates
www.theigc.org/newsletter
Follow us on Twitter
@the_igc
Contact us
International GrowthCentre,
London School ofEconomic
and Political Science,
Houghton Street,
LondonWC2A 2AE