5757 S. University Ave.
Chicago, IL 60637
Main: 773.702.5599
bfi.uchicago.edu
WORKING PAPER · NO. 2020-19
Kill Zone
Sai Krishna Kamepalli, Raghuram G. Rajan, and Luigi Zingales
MARCH 2020
1
Kill Zone
Sai Krishna Kamepalli Raghuram Rajan Luigi Zingales*
University of Chicago University of Chicago & NBER
This version: March 2020
First draft: November 2019
Abstract
We study why high-priced acquisitions of entrants by an incumbent do not necessarily stimulate
more innovation and entry in an industry (like that of digital platforms) where customers face
switching costs and enjoy network externalities. The prospect of an acquisition by the incumbent
platform undermines early adoption by customers, reducing prospective payoffs to new entrants.
This creates a “kill zone” in the start-up space, as described by venture capitalists, where new
ventures are not worth funding. Evidence from changes in investment in startups by venture
capitalists after major acquisitions by Facebook and Google suggests this is more than a mere
theoretical possibility.
*
Rajan acknowledges support from the Fama-Miller Center and the Stigler Center at the University of Chicago.
Zingales also acknowledges financial support from the Stigler Center. We thank Filippo Lancieri and Fiona Scott
Morton for very useful comments.
2
There is a growing worry that digital platforms (multi-sided markets that offer digital
services to customers, often for free, in exchange for data) might be gaining market power,
distorting competition, and slowing innovation. A specific concern is that such platforms might
acquire any potential competitors, dissuading others from entering, and thus preventing
innovation from serving as the competitive threat that is traditionally believed to keep monopoly
incumbents on their toes. In a sense, they create a “Kill Zone around their areas of activity. For
instance, Albert Wenger, a managing partner at Union Square Ventures and an early investor in
Twitter recently declared “The Kill Zone is a real thing. The scale of these companies [digital
platforms] and their impact on what can be funded, and what can succeed, is massive.”
1
Consistent with this idea, Figure 1 shows that the number and the dollar value of new start-ups in
the social media space have dropped dramatically in the last few years.
Yet, this decline in the raw numbers could be driven by a lot of other concurrent factors.
Most importantly, the idea that acquisitions discourage new investments is at odds with a
standard economic argument (see Phillips and Zhdanov (2013), and for related evidence); if
incumbents pay handsomely to acquire new entrants, why should entry be curtailed? Why would
the prospect of an acquisition not be an extra incentive for entrepreneurs to enter the space, in the
hope of being acquired at hefty multiples?
In this paper we argue that this standard economic argument relies critically on the value
at which firms are acquired being adequate compensation for innovation. This may not hold in
the context of acquisitions by digital platforms, because the economics of digital platforms differ
significantly from the neoclassical economics of firms taught in standard textbooks. To show
this, we build a simple model of platform competition that contains the key novel ingredients
present in this space: First, they are two-sided in that one side faces advertisers while the other
side faces customers for the service, which is often priced at zero. As a result, there isn’t any
price competition on the customer side. Second, there are important network externalities on the
customer side of the market. Third, customers face switching costs.
1
https://promarket.org/google-facebooks-kill-zone-weve-taken-focus-off-rewarding-genius-innovation-rewarding-
capital-scale/ . Also see the Economist (2018) https://www.economist.com/business/2018/06/02/american-tech-
giants-are-making-life-tough-for-startups, Assessing the Impact of Big Tech on Venture Investment, OLIVER WYMAN
(July 11, 2018), https://www.oliverwyman.com/content/dam/oliver-wyman/v2/publications/2018/july/assessing-
impact.pdf, and Ian Hathaway, Platform Giants and Venture-Backed Startups, IAN HATHAWAY BLOG (Oct. 12,
2018), http://www.ianhathaway.org/blog/2018/10/12/platform-giants-and-venture-backed-startups
3
In this context we show that a crucial role in the success of an innovation is played by
early adopters amongst customers, whom we shall term “techies”. Techies choose their favored
platform mainly for its technical characteristics, and have the incentive to uncover the underlying
quality of each rival platform. The mass of early techie adopters, in turn, drives the adoption by
ordinary non-techie customers for two reasons. First, the mass of techie adopters offers a signal
about the fundamental quality improvement brought about by the new platform. Second, this
mass creates a network externality for ordinary customers, who have to choose whether to adopt
the new platform.
Consider the decision of techies. They care primarily about the fundamental technical
quality of the platform. However, they also engage deeply in any technology, so they have high
switching costs (of learning every minor aspect of any platform they adopt). If techies expect
two platforms to merge, they will be reluctant to pay the switching costs and adopt the new
platform early on, unless the new platform significantly outperforms the incumbent one. After
all, they know that if the entering platform’s technology is a net improvement over the existing
technology, it will be adopted by the merged entity. Thus, the prospect of a merger will dissuade
many techies from trying the new technology. By staying with the incumbent, however, they
reduce the stand-alone value of the entering platform.
The stand-alone market value of the entering platform is driven both by its perceived
quality and the total number of customers who adopt it (because of network externalities). Yet,
this number depends crucially on the number of techies who adopt it, which in turn depends on
the expectation this platform would indeed stand alone. Since the stand-alone value represents
the entrant’s reservation value in any merger negotiation with the incumbent, the prospect of a
future acquisition can sufficiently reduce adoption by techies, and thus the entrant’s payoff, so as
to discourage more entry.
2
Think about early-adopter as bees: in pursuing their own interest they generate a positive
externality. Because of this externality, any environmental condition that affects bees’ incentives
to roam across flowers has a much bigger effect than its direct effect on bees’ welfare. The same
is true here. Any environmental condition that reduces the techies’ incentives to search for better
2
There is a parallel here to exclusionary conduct. If everyone expects the incumbent to use exclusionary contracts
(or other anticompetitive behavior) to prevent customers from leaving, this expectation alone will decrease the value
of any new entrant. In turn, this will discourage entry. The point here is that the exclusionary conduct may simply
occur by the very nature of online platforms, network externalities, and switching costs.
4
platforms and switch to them has a negative effect on the system. By contrast, any environmental
condition that increases the techies’ incentives to search for better platforms and switch to them
has a positive effect on the system.
If it is so important for an entrant to signal that she will not sell out to the incumbent, why
doesn’t she commit to it? An entrant entrepreneur will try her best to portray fierce
independence, committing to uphold the “purity” of her new technology. In fact, the often-
claimed presence of super egotistic CEOs/founders, driven more by a vision than by money, can
be interpreted as an attempt to commit credibly not to sell the platform. Nevertheless, in a world
of rational agents it is hard to see how the entrepreneur can credibly commit not to sell when
selling maximizes her profits (given that a monopolist’s profits are greater than the sum of the
profits of two duopolists). This is where antitrust enforcement can help. If a large incumbent is
prevented by regulation from acquiring new platforms operating in a similar space, then entrant
entrepreneurs are credibly committed not to sell. This commitment will increase the valuation of
new entrants, stimulating investments in technological improvements and entry.
From a welfare point of view, these restrictions on mergers will have costs: if the market
remains segmented, network externalities will be lower than otherwise achievable, and some
customers will not enjoy a superior technology. If the market eventually converges to the
superior technology, too many customers would have to pay the switching costs. Thus, the social
optimum will not be an outright prohibition or complete laissez faire, but some middle-of-the
road policy, which will trade off the ex-post welfare losses produced by merger restrictions
against the ex-ante gains in investments in innovation.
Let us turn to evidence. Since companies are reluctant to engage in acquisitions that will
be blocked by antitrust, the announcement of an acquisition signals that antitrust authorities are
likely to allow acquisitions in a certain space. Under this assumption, a counter-intuitive
implication of our model is that acquisitions of new entrants at generous multiples by incumbent
digital platforms can lead to a decrease in new entry and a decrease in the amounts invested in
similar businesses at similar stages of development.
The novelty of the phenomenon and the paucity of acquisitions by large incumbent
platforms do not allow an in depth analysis. Nevertheless, we analyze whether the limited data
available are consistent with the model. We collect data on the number of deals and dollar
amounts invested by the venture capitalist in specific sectors, after major acquisitions by
5
Facebook and Google are announced. We find that, relative to the mean in the entire software
sector, VC investments in start-ups in the same space as the company acquired by Google and
Facebook drop by 40% and the number of deals by 43% in the three years following an
acquisition. Similarly, the financing of new startups in the same space decreased by 51%
relative to the financing of all new start-ups in the software industry.
We consider alternative explanations of these results, including the possibility that most
(if not all) the start-ups similar to the ones acquired by Google or Facebook were created with
the only objective of being acquired by Google or Facebook. Thus, when the two tech giants
chose other targets, the potential alternatives lose their likely buyer and thus financing. To
address this concern, we only look at startups that are in a similar space, but not too close to the
space of the acquired ones (so that they cannot be considered perfect substitutes). Our results are
if anything stronger. We also consider the possibility of the acquired start-up being a
complement rather than a substitute to the incumbent platform.
While this limited evidence can only be considered suggestive, it is consistent with the
most counterintuitive implications of the model. It would be premature to draw any policy
conclusion on antitrust enforcement based solely on our model and our limited evidence. Yet,
our model can help us think what other type of policies may increase innovation in digital
platforms, if the concerns about a “kill zone” are warranted. For example, the more an incumbent
can freely copy the technological innovations of new entrants, the worse the incentives of early
adopters to switch to a new entrant will be. These reduced incentives will lower the stand-alone
valuation of new entrants and thus lower the return to innovation. This result is not specific to
digital platforms: the ability to copy freely an innovation always reduces the incentives to invest.
What is new is the extent of the problem. In the usual setting, the incumbent’s ability to copy
reduces, but does not eliminate, the profitability of the innovator. In our setting, if the incumbent
can freely copy the new features of an entrant, the new entrant will be left with insignificant
profits since no one will switch.
Importantly, innovation increases if we increase interoperability across platforms (i.e., we
make network externalities available to all). As the new entrant obtains the incumbent’s network
externalities, competition primarily focuses on the intrinsic quality differences, increasing the
return to innovation. If there is a policy conclusion to be drawn from our model, it is this:
6
interoperability across platforms helps resolve many of the distortions in digital platforms
because it reduces the incumbency advantage from network externalities and switching costs.
Schumpeter (1934, 1942) are, of course, the seminal works on incentives to innovate and
competition. He noted, among other effects, the possibility that the incumbent monopolist has a
lower incentive to innovate for fear of cannibalizing its existing technology, a higher incentive to
innovate for fear of losing the monopoly entirely, and a greater incentive to innovate given the
size of the market it has access to. Aghion et al. (2005) subsequently argue for an inverted U
shaped relationship between competition and innovation.
The classic analysis of the effect of antitrust enforcement on incentives to innovate is
Segal and Whinston (2007). In their model, where there are no network externalities, voluntary
licensing agreements (and equally mergers) raise both parties’ payoffs and thus increase
innovation. In this framework, Cabral (2018) introduces the distinction between radical
innovation (competition for the market) and incremental innovation (competition within the
market). He shows that antitrust restrictions on acquisitions (or technology transfers) can lead to
lower incremental innovation but higher radical innovation. The negative impact of mergers on
radical innovation, however, comes from an “opportunity cost" effect. By increasing the payoff
of incremental innovation, mergers reduce the additional payoff of radical innovation. In our
model we have only radical innovation. Nevertheless, mergers can reduce the incentive to
innovate because of the impact they have on the acquisition of customers.
On the empirical side, Phillips and Zhdanov (2013) provide evidence consistent with the
idea that a more active market for mergers and acquisitions encourages innovation by small
firms, while enabling larger firms to optimally outsource R&D to them. By contrast, Seru (2014)
finds that firms acquired in diversifying mergers tend to reduce the scale and novelty of R&D
activity relative to potential targets that escaped being acquired. He finds that the effect is
centered around inventors becoming less productive after mergers, and associates it with the
centralized nature of conglomerates reducing incentives to innovate. Phillips and Zhdanov
reconcile their results with Seru’s by arguing that large firms (such as conglomerates) have lower
incentives to innovate, and prefer acquiring innovative small firms, and this may be an
appropriate division of labor. Our paper, of course, focuses on a subset of acquisitions –
specifically, acquisitions by platforms – and explains why the analysis and outcomes may be
different there.
7
Cunningham, Ederer, and Ma (2018) examine acquisitions by pharmaceutical companies
and find that acquired drug projects are less likely to be taken to full development when they
overlap with the acquirer’s existing drug portfolio, especially when the acquirer faces limited
competition and has a long time to expiry on existing drug patents. While such “killer
acquisitions” may stop further R&D on competing products and pre-empt future competition,
they may also reduce resultant product quality. Cunningham et al. do not focus on how this alters
ex ante incentives to innovate, the central concern in our work.
Another related paper is Wen and Zhu (2019). They examine how app developers on the
Android mobile platform alter efforts as the threat of Google’s entry increases. They find that
developers reduce innovation and raise prices (in an attempt to milk their value before actual
Google entry) for the affected apps. They also find developers shift efforts to unaffected areas.
Of course, their focus is not on acquisition but on competition from the platform. Relatedly, a
number of policy papers assess the costs and benefits of platform acquisitions (see, for example,
Bourreau (2019) and Hylton (2019)).
In the law literature, a number of scholars have focused on the unique attributes of online
platforms in necessitating a rethink of antitrust law and practice. Khan (2019) argues that
platform owners control access to customers and when they sell services on the platform, have a
special ability to foreclose competitors. Wu (2018) argues that a variety of network products
compete for customer attention, and ought to be seen as competitors when traditional antitrust
theory would ordinarily dismiss any competitive link. In a similar vein, we focus on the network
externalities and switching costs associated with online platforms to argue why they could have
substantial impact.
Finally, Bryan and Hovenkamp (2019) present a theory of competition amongst innovating
firms and find that start-ups are biased towards innovations that help the leader increase its lead
after acquisition (which eventually diminishes competition and innovation as the leader’s
advantage increases) rather than help a follower catch up (which would increase the competitive
pressure in the industry to innovate). They argue that mandating compulsory licensing of new
technologies when the startup’s acquirer is dominant in the industry may help preserve
competition and incentives for startups to innovate. Unlike us, their focus is not on industries
where there are two sided platforms with network externalities. Our work should be thought of as
complementary to theirs.
8
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. We outline the model in section 1, describe the
data in section 2, report the results in section 3, discuss possible extensions in section 4, and
conclude in section 5.
1. The Model
1.1 Set-Up
Consider an incumbent platform I, which is threatened by a new entrant platform E.
Without loss of generality, we will assume the quality of the incumbent is normalized to zero.
The quality increment of the new entrant,
θ
, is realized from an uniform distribution
,
θθ


,
where
0
θθ
≤<
. There are two groups of customers: techies with measure
λ
and ordinary
customers with measure 1. We consider two periods and three dates with date t denoting the
end of period t.
Techies are early adopters. At date 0 (the beginning of the first period), techies observe a
public signal
q
θε
= +
about E’s quality increment relative to I, where
is random noise,
distributed normally with mean 0 and precision
α
. Having observed the signal, the techies decide
whether to switch to the new entrant or not. For the techies, the per-period incremental utility of
switching is driven entirely by the incremental technical quality of the platform (i.e., they do not
benefit from network externalities, which we will define shortly). If they switch, techies need to
spend time to understand the new technology thoroughly, so each techie i faces a one-time
switching cost
i
s
to move to the new platform.
3
Techie switching costs are uniformly distributed
over
[0, ]s
. The future is assumed discounted at a gross interest rate of 1, and all agents are risk
neutral, expected utility maximizers.
At date 1, the two companies decide whether to merge or not. The share of the merged
value each party gets is determined through a bargaining process we will specify shortly. If they
do merge, the superior technology – which is the entrant’s if
0
θ
>
-- will be adopted by the
merged entity and all the customers will enjoy it, regardless of whether they had switched before
or not. The acquirer in the merger ensures a smooth transition to all customers so that switching
3
Equivalently, since the techie’s utility from switching is
i
qs
,
i
s
could be the techie’s private signal about
quality.
9
costs are minimized thereafter (to zero). If the two companies do not merge, they will survive
1n
periods independently – think of this period as the lifecycle of the technology.
Ordinary customers do not have sufficient information to switch in the first period. In the
second period, they are confronted with the decision of whether to switch only if the merger fails
to go through. Their switching decision is not based only on the expected technical
characteristics of the new platform, but also on the number of customers (techie and ordinary) a
platform is able to attract/retain. Thus, ordinary customers do experience some network
externalities. Specifically, for an ordinary customer the benefit of a platform is given by the sum
of its expected quality and the total measure of consumers (techie and ordinary) who opt for it.
At the beginning of period 2, ordinary customers have two pieces of information in
making their switching decision: i) they observe how many techies switched in period 1
4
; ii)
they also see a private signal of incremental entrant quality,
ii
x
θη
= +
, where
i
η
is random noise,
distributed normally with mean zero and precision
β
. For simplicity, ordinary customers have no
switching costs, though these are easily handled. They also do not switch again in the future,
after this initial switching decision. The timeline is as follows.
What we now determine is the measure of techies that switch, and its anticipated effect
on switching behavior by ordinary customers if the merger does not take place. This will then
affect the target price that the incumbent will offer the entrant to merge. We postpone discussion
of the merger till the next subsection.
4
Practically, this may reflect the volume of buzz in the market (or lack of it) about the product, and write-ups by the
tech correspondents of various newspapers, magazines, or informative websites.
10
1.2 Analysis of Switching Behavior
In making their decision at date 0, techies know that if they switch they will enjoy a
product of quality
q
for
(1 )
m
+
periods, where m=0 if the merger takes place at date 1, and m=n
if it does not. As a result, each techie will decide to switch comparing this benefit with her
personal cost of switching. Thus, she will switch if and only if
(1 )
i
mq s+>
.
Given that techies’ switching cost is uniformly distributed, the measure of techies who switch in
the first period is given by
(1 )mq
s
λ
+
if
(1 )
01
mq
s
+
≤≤
, 0 if
(1 )
0
mq
s
+
<
and
λ
otherwise. To
simplify the notation in the rest of the paper we will assume that
(1 )
01
mq
s
+
≤≤
.
5
Clearly, the
longer the period m that the firms will remain independent, the more each techie who switches
enjoys the incremental quality of the entrant, and the more the fraction of techies who find it
worthwhile to incur switching costs. The measure of techies who remain with the incumbent is
(1 )
[1 ]
mq
s
λ
+
.
After the first period, ordinary customers observe how many techies have switched. Since
they know m, they can back out q, the techies’ public signal. Combining with the private signal
they observe at the beginning of period 2, each ordinary customer i will have a posterior belief
of the quality differential with mean
i
ρ
=
i
qx
αβ
αβ
+
+
and precision
αβ
+
. Assuming the merger
has not taken place, the ordinary customer’s decision to switch depends upon (i) his posterior
belief of the quality differential between platforms and (ii) his estimate of the size of customers
who will choose each platform and provide network externalities. He will switch if and only if
the network-externality-adjusted quality of the entrant is superior, that is, iff
(1 ) (1 )
() (1 ())
ii i
mq mq
pp
ss
λλ
ρρ ρλ
++

+ + ≥− +


,
The first term on the left hand side is his perception of the quality differential, the second is his
measure
()
i
p
ρ
of ordinary customers he believes will switch to the entrant based on his
5
We avoid having to deal with truncated expressions with this assumption, but it changes nothing material.
11
perception of the quality differential, and the third term is the measure of techies who have
already switched. The second and third term thus represent the network externalities realized
from switching. The first term on the right hand side is the measure of ordinary customers he
believes will not switch, and the second is the measure of techies who have not switched. The
sum represents the network externalities from staying with the incumbent. This inequality can be
rewritten as
(1 )
2( ) (1 ) 0
i
mq
p
s
λ
ρλ
+
+ + −+
.
1.2 The Switching Game
The ordinary customers decision is typical in a global game (see, for example, Morris and Shin,
2000, 2003).
6
To solve it, we first conjecture that ordinary customers will follow a switching
strategy where they switch if their prior of quality exceeds a threshold
*
ρ
. When an ordinary
customer at the cusp of switching observes a signal
i
x
(and thus has a posterior belief
*
i
ρρ
=
)
and chooses to switch, he will have to assume that a fraction p will switch as well, i.e. a fraction
p should have a posterior at least as high as his. Since
Pr{ | } 1 Pr{ | }
j ii j ii
ρ ρρ ρ ρρ
> =−≤
, we
need to determine the probability that
ji
ρρ
. Conditional on
i
ρ
, will be distributed with a
mean
i
ρ
and a precision
1
11
αβ β
+
+
()
2
βα β
αβ
+
=
+
.
Thus, we can write
Pr{ | }
j ii
ρ ρρ
=
Pr{ | }
j
ii
qx
αβ
ρρ
αβ
+
+
=
Pr{ ( ) | }
ji i i
xq
α
ρρρ
β
≤+
=
Pr{ ( ) | }
ji i i
q
α
η ρ ρ θρ
β
+ −−
. But since
|
ii
θρ ρ
=
, this equals
Pr{ ( ) | }
jii
q
α
η ρρ
β
≤−
=
( )
()
i
q
γρ
Φ−
where
Φ
is the cumulative standard normal distribution and
(
)
2
()
2
αβα
γ
α ββ
+
=
+
.
6
We structure it as a global game to obtain a unique solution. Without the global game structure we would have to
focus on a specific equilibrium.
12
For
*i
ρρ
=
to be the switching threshold, a necessary condition is that
**
(1 )
2( ( ) ) (1 ) 0
mq
p
s
λ
ρρ λ
+
+ + −+ =
or
( )
**
(1 )
2(1 ( ) ) (1 ) 0
mq
q
s
λ
ρ γρ λ
+
+ −Φ + + =
(1)
( )
**
(1 )
2 2 (1 ) 2 ( ) 0
mq
q
s
λ
ρ λ γρ
+
+ + + −Φ =
.
Let
(
)
(1 )
( ) 2 2 (1 ) 2 ( )
mq
Sq
s
λ
ρ ρ λ γρ
+
= + + + −Φ −
. For
*
i
ρρ
=
to be the switching
equilibrium, it should be the case that
()S
ρ
is increasing in
given the parameters
(, )qm
.
Theorem 1: For
2
π
γ
<
the function
()S
ρ
is always increasing in
ρ
given
(, )qm
and there is a
unique switching equilibrium.
Proof: Given
(, )qm
the function
()
S
ρ
is always increasing in
ρ
if
()
0
dS
d
ρ
ρ
>
( )
()
0 1 (2 ) ( ) 0
dS
q
d
ρ
γφγρ
ρ
> ⇒− >
( )
1
()
2
q
φγρ
γ
−<
2
1 ( ( )) 1
exp
22
2
q
γρ
γ
π

−−
<


2
2
22
( ) ln( )
2
q
π
ρ
γγ
−>
This condition will always hold for
2
π
γ
<
. Then,
()S
ρ
is always increasing in
ρ
and hence
the optimal switching point
*
ρ
is the only solution of .
QED
13
The following figure shows the variation of optimal switching point for
0.4
λ
=
,
4s =
,
300
α
=
,
100
β
=
,
[0,1]
θ
.
For a given n, we can see that as the public signal of early switching q increases, the
optimal switching point for ordinary customers decreases. Furthermore, for a given q, the
optimal switching point decreases as the number of subsequent periods n increase since more
techies switch for any given q.
This chart immediately suggests the following corollaries:
Corollary 1: The optimal switching point decreases and the fraction of ordinary customers
switching to the new technology increases in the number of periods (1+m) that the techie expects
the entrant to remain independent.
Proof: Total differentiation of
*
()0S
ρ
=
given q:
( )
( )
**
1 (2 ) ( ) 2 0
q
q d dm
s
λ
γφγρ ρ
+=
( )
( )
*
*
2
< 0 if
2
1 (2 ) ( )
q
d
s
dm
q
λ
ρπ
γ
γφγρ
= <
−−
14
Intuitively, the longer the period the firms will remain independent, the more techies will switch
to the entrant for a given positive public signal q, increasing the network externalities associated
with the entrant. In turn, this will reduce the quality threshold at which ordinary customers will
switch to the entrant if the merger did not take place, enhancing the expected value of the entrant
as a stand-alone entity.
Corollary 2: The optimal switching point decreases and the fraction of ordinary customers
switching to the new technology increases with a higher public signal.
Proof: Total differentiation of
*
()0S
ρ
=
given m:
( )
( )
(
)
** *
(1 )
1 (2 ) ( ) 2 (2 ) ( ) 0
m
q d q dq
s
λ
γφγρ ρ γφγρ
+

+ + −=


( )
( )
( )
*
*
*
(1 )
2 (2 ) ( )
< 0 if
2
1 (2 ) ( )
m
q
d
s
dq
q
λ
γφγρ
ρπ
γ
γφγρ
+
−−
= <
−−
The following figure presents the above two results with
*
()p
ρ
being the proportion of ordinary
customers shifting to the new technology. For
0.4
λ
=
,
4s =
,
300
α
=
,
100
β
=
,
[0,1]
θ
.
15
1.3 The merger game
To further simplify notation in what follows, we will assume that the quality of the entrant is
always weakly higher (that is,
0
θ
=
), so that if the merger takes place, the entrant’s technology
will be espoused.
By merging, the two platforms will generate over the n periods together
[ ( 1) ( 1)1]
T
Wn
θλ λ
= ++ +
in total welfare – the first term is the quality increment of the entrant, which is now enjoyed by
all, and the second is the network externality enjoyed by ordinary customers, which is
maximized because all customers are on the same platform. The per-period welfare within square
brackets is multiplied by the number of periods to get total welfare. It can be rewritten as
[( 1)( 1)]n
λθ
++
.
If the bargaining game breaks down, the surplus produced by the entrant E is given by
(1 ) (1 ) (1 )
( , ) [ ( ) ( ) ] [( )( )]
EM M MM M M
mq mq mq
Wpq p ppn p p n
ss s
θλ λ λ θ
++ +
= ++ + = + +
16
where
M
p
is the proportion of ordinary customers switching. Note that the proportion of
ordinary customers switching is based on the techies’ assumption that the merger would have
taken place (i.e., that
0m =
). This is appropriate since we are considering the out-of-
equilibrium possibility that a merger, which was anticipated, does not take place.
The surplus produced by the incumbent is given by network externality enjoyed by the
ordinary “remainers”, which is
(1 )
( , ) [(( 1) )(1 )]
IM M M
mq
Wpq p p n
s
λλ
+
= +−
,
Since
2qs
and
1
M
p
, then it is easy to see that
T EI
WWW≥+
, so the merger is always ex-
post efficient. This is not surprising since we have assumed bringing all the customers under the
same platform will maximize the number of people enjoying the superior technology and the
network externalities.
7
Therefore, if mergers are not restricted by the antitrust authorities, a merger will always
take place because it is efficient. The only question is at what price the transaction will take
place. To discuss the price, we need to determine the profitability of the incumbent and the
entrant, under the various scenarios. This is complicated by the fact that these are two-sided
platforms, which charge zero on the consumer side of the market and make profits only on the
advertising side. Since advertising generates negative utility to customers, the amount of a
platform’s advertising is limited by the consumer surplus the platform generates. Thus, we
assume that by advertising a platform can extract in profits all the surplus it generates on the
consumer side. In such a case, the price an entrant will pay in a merger is given by a bargaining
game where we assume she can fully appropriate the surplus she generates under alternative
scenarios.
If a merger takes place, we assume that with probability
µ
the incumbent makes a take-
it-or-leave-it offer to the entrant. With probability
1
µ
, it is the other way around. Thus, the
entrant’s payoff in case of merger is
( ,) ( ,) (1 )[ ( ,)]
EM EM T IM
pq Wpq W Wpq
µµ
Π = +−
In case a merger is prohibited by the antitrust, the payoff of the entrant is given by
7
Of course, if the incumbent’s technology were superior, the incumbent would want to use its own technology, but
would still make an offer to the entrant, so as to benefit from the network externalities associated with its customers.
Mergers are always efficient, regardless of who has the technological advantage.
17
(1 ) (1 )
( ,) ( ,) [( ) ( ) ]
E NM E NM NM NM NM
nq nq
pqWpq p ppn
ss
θλ λ
++
Π = = ++ +
.
Note that
( ,) ( ,)
E NM E M
Wp qWpq
because
1n
and
NM M
pp>
because of Corollary 1 – given
the longer horizon m that switching techies have when mergers are not permitted, more will
switch for any given q, lowering the threshold for ordinary customers to switch, and enhancing
the measure of ordinary customers that switch to the entrant. Hence, if the entrant’s bargaining
power is zero, her payoff is larger when mergers are prohibited, even if the prohibition on
mergers leads to firms not fully exploiting the network externalities and the technological gains.
Intuitively, if mergers are prohibited an entrant will attract a greater customer base for
two reasons. First, in period 1, anticipating a longer period over which they will enjoy the quality
differential, a greater set of techies will switch. Second, the greater number of techies will
generate a greater network externality which will attract an even greater number of ordinary
customers. Since she attracts more customers when mergers are prohibited, a new entrant will
generate more surplus by itself under this scenario than in the scenario where the merger is
anticipated to occur.
More generally, if her bargaining power is small, the entrant’s payoff will be driven
mostly by her outside option. Since we just showed that her outside option is bigger when
mergers are prohibited, the entrant’s payoff will be bigger when mergers are prohibited.
In practice, it is very difficult to prohibit mergers entirely. At best, a regulator can impose
a very strict pre-merger notification rule and adopt a very careful review process. Such rules,
however, might have the effect of making the acquisition more difficult, not eliminating it.
Nevertheless, this intervention can still be useful. For our effect to work we do not need an
absolute prohibition, but just some uncertainty on the final outcome. With sufficient uncertainty
on when and whether a merger will take place, the techies will be prompted to switch, increasing
the value of potential entrants.
1.4 Ex Ante Investment
Thus far, we have assumed that the technological improvement
was manna from heaven. More
realistically, this improvement is the result of some ex-ante investment made by the potential
entrant. Let’s assume that the potential entrant will face a cost
E
C
of R&D, drawn from a
distribution. On paying this cost, she can draw a technology of quality
θ
from a distribution.
18
Before she decides whether to enter, E will compare her expected profit with her known cost of
R&D and enter if and only if
[ ( )]
EE
EC
θ
θ
Π>
. Prohibiting acquisitions by incumbent platforms
can have the effect of increasing the expected profit of new entrants for any
θ
(for example, if
1
µ
in the merger negotiations, so that incumbents have tremendous bargaining power). This
will increase the range of
E
C
that are viable, and increase the probability of investment in R&D
and thus entry.
Notice that this result will hold even when prohibiting acquisitions is socially inefficient
because of the ex post inefficiencies this policy generates. Thus, finding empirically that
acquisitions lead to lower entry does not automatically imply that prohibiting acquisitions is the
right policy. Nevertheless, our intent was to determine circumstances under which something as
seemingly beneficial to the acquired as an acquisition offer could actually deter entry.
1.5. Determinants of Bargaining Power
The implications of the theoretical exercise are that events that indicate the anti-trust
authorities are more lenient in permitting platform acquisitions could potentially reduce entry in
areas that are closely relatedsince observers will conclude that the anti-trust authorities will be
similarly lenient in the case of the entrant. Of course, the theory suggests this is most likely when
the incumbent has tremendous bargaining power. Before we turn to the data, let us discuss what
might determine the incumbent’s bargaining power, which we set in the model to a generic
µ
.
Notice that within our model a lower
µ
will always improve efficiency, since it will not
affect the decisions ex post, but it will increase investments and entry ex ante. This might not be
true in a general model, where the incumbent also invests in innovation. Furthermore, any
incumbent is a former start-up, thus the model should not be taken literally as suggesting
minimizing
µ
is optimal. This said, there are several reasons to believe that
µ
is rather large in
practice.
First, in a standard Rubinstein (1981) game, the bargaining power
µ
is inversely related
to the degree of impatience or the discount rate. The cost of capital of an incumbent – having
undertaken a successful and often lucrative IPO, and enjoying a high stock price -- is much
smaller than the cost of capital of an entrant. This difference alone could explain why
might be
close to 1.
19
Another important factor in determining the degree of impatience is the threat of replication.
If the incumbent is allowed to copy the new entrant’s innovation, the longer the period over
which bargaining takes place, the higher the risk of replication. This increases E’s impatience
and thus I’s bargaining power.
In many real world situations, negotiations take place under the veiled (and sometimes not so
veiled) threat by the incumbent to drive the entrant out of business with aggressive behavior if
she does not sell out. The incumbent’s threat is maximized when it can easily replicate the
technological features of the new entrant (see above). But even without this possibility, there are
many ways in which an incumbent can make the new entrant’s life difficult: from slashing prices
on the revenue side of the platform to use its lobbying power. Most (if not all) these behaviors
could be deterred by an active antitrust authority, but the recent historical record on this front has
been quite weak.
8
The awareness of this historical record can only increase the incumbent’s
bargaining power.
Last but not least, in the presence of network externalities, markets tend to be winner-take-
all. Thus, the risk for any participant is not to be worth less: it is to be worth zero. Entrants are
less suited to bear this risk, since they tend to have a more concentrated ownership structure than
established incumbents whose shareholders are better diversified. This comparative disadvantage
in bearing the risk of failure further weakens the entrant’s bargaining power vis-à-vis the
incumbent.
1.6. Negative Prices
One important assumption in our analysis is that prices for platform services are non-
negative. Traditionally, this has been the case, but recently several companies have tried to find
ways around this constraint. There are three major obstacles to pay people for using a platform.
First, transactions costs can quickly mount, since each transaction tends to have a very low price.
Second, there is the risk of abuse: arbitrageurs can design bots to benefit from payments intended
for real people. Third, while in principle the platform with the superior technology should be
able to offer the highest rebate, in practice liquidity constraints severely restrict new entrants’
ability to pay.
8
See, for example, the battle between Quidsi and Amazon detailed in Khan (2017) and Stone (2013).
20
The internet browser Brave has launched a reward system to pay customers for using its
product and watching its ads.
9
To get around the afore-mentioned problems, Brave chose to pay
users with its own bitcoin-style cryptocurrency called Basic Attention Tokens or BAT. BATs
are utility tokens that are not convertible into dollars, but can be used to buy ads from Brave at a
pre-determinate price. The idea is that their value will increase with the use of the browser. If
in addition—these tokens are traded, their values can signal to unsophisticated customers the
value of the new technology. Indeed, Li and Mann (2019) have shown that token offerings can
help resolve coordination problems.
A system of token-based payment can help mitigate the problems highlighted in this
paper. We say “mitigate” since such tokens offered to techies can help them internalize the
network externalities later faced by ordinary customers, giving them an added incentive to switch
when the entrant technology is superior. However, the underlying effects of switching costs and
the horizon-reducing effects of mergers will not be eliminated.
1.7. Internalizing the externality
A more effective alternative to paying customers is to subsidize techies to switch to the new
platform, since they have a multiplicative effect on the number of customers who will eventually
switch. In today’s world these techies are called “influencers” and are indeed paid to induce
people to switch. If it is known that switchers are paid, then the type of inference regular
customers make when they observe a techie switching is very different from the one assumed in
our model. Nevertheless, to the extent their action does signal some information, paying for
influencers makes sense.
While the possibility of paying for influencers might reduce the frequency with which
superior platforms may succumb to incumbents, it does not eliminate (in fact, it might
exacerbate) the ex-ante suboptimal incentives to invest in creating improvements for platforms.
In fact, the influencers are capturing part of a rent they did not help create, thereby reducing the
return to the people doing the actual investing.
9
https://www.wired.com/story/brave-browser-will-pay-surf-web/.
21
1.8. Substitute and Complements
We have cast our model in terms of substitutes: an incumbent platform threatened by an
alternative new platform. Yet, some of the major acquisitions done by Google are complements:
take for instance the acquisition of Doubleclick, a company that displayed and tracks banner ads
across a network of websites. Our model can easily be restated in term of complements to the
incumbent platform.
Assume the complement company (Doubleclick) provides an essential service that makes
the platform (Google) more attractive to users (in this case, firms). Assume that the platform
already provides that service, but in a less effective way. If the platform is prohibited from
acquiring the complement, users will switch for the particular complementary function to
contract separately with the complement producer, enhancing its value from the network
externalities (in this case, the additional information it gets from diverse users to improve its
product). If the platform can acquire the complement, potential switchers may be reluctant to
incur switching costs, continuing to use the lower quality service provided by the platform until
the acquisition takes place. Given that the complement is thus also lower quality as a stand-alone
entity (having attracted fewer switchers and having less data to use in product development), its
acquisition price will be lower than if mergers had been prohibited. The rest of the implications
follow.
There is an additional issue with complements. If there is only one monopoly incumbent
platform that can possibly acquire the complement, then once the acquisition takes place, the
remaining budding firms providing that complement have no more market. It is not surprising
that investment in them will fall precipitously. Of course, if the platform market is oligopolistic,
it gets a little more complicated. Once a complement is acquired by a platform, there is a smaller
market available for the remaining complements to either sell their services to as independent
firms or to sell themselves to. This should depress the acquisition price and investment in such
firms. There is another effect, though. If there are only a few such complements available, the
remaining platforms may bid vigorously in order to match the services provided by the platform
that has already bought one. The net effect on acquisition prices and investment is ambiguous.
There is a final possibility one where Doubleclick is not valuable as a stand-alone
company, but only in combination with one of the existing digital platforms. Let’s assume that
there is an incumbent platform (Google) and a challenger (Bing). The price that Doubleclick can
22
obtain from Google depends upon Bing’s bid for Doubleclick. But Bing’s bid for Doubleclick
depends upon the number of customers who are willing to switch to Bing. If Google’s customers
anticipate that the acquisition of Doubleclick will take place and that the combination Google-
Doubleclick will be superior, they have little incentive to switch to Bing, even if Bing (before
Google’s acquisition of Doubleclick) was technological superior. This resistance to switching
will reduce not only the value of Bing, but also the price that Bing is able to offer to Doubleclick
and thus, ultimately, the price Google will have to pay to acquire Doubleclick. By contrast, if
there is uncertainty whether the Google-Doubleclick merger would be allowed, more Google
customers will be willing to try and switch to Bing, increasing the amount of value Bing creates
by buying Doubleclick. As a result, Bing would be able to bid higher for Doubleclick, increasing
the price at which Doubleclick will be bought. In this case, network externalities and switching
costs do not depress the value of the platform itself, but the value of the complement to the
platforms, reducing their incentives to invest.
2. The Data
The model presented above explains why banning mergers may positively affect innovation and
investment. Ideally, we would like to study the impact on start-up investments of a decision by
antitrust authorities to strike down a big acquisition by a major digital platform. Unfortunately,
we have not observed any such decision yet. Therefore, we need to resort to a different strategy.
Big companies are unlikely to decide a major acquisition without having a fairly high
degree of confidence that such an acquisition will be accepted. Thus, we will consider the
announcements of major acquisitions as a signal that the US Federal Trade Commission and the
Department of Justice will let these, and similar, acquisitions go through. We then see the impact
on investment decisions by related early stage companies.
We focus on the major acquisitions of software companies conducted by Facebook and
Google from the beginning of 2006 to the end of 2018. We focus on Facebook and Google
because they are two prominent incumbent two-sided platforms that charge a zero monetary
price on one side of the market, as described in the model. We restrict attention to their major
acquisitions because we think that only those acquisitions convey a strong signal on the future
antitrust attitude towards acquisitions. Finally, we focus on software companies because we are
looking for start-ups that can develop into potential competitors of the incumbent platforms.
23
The source of our data is Pitchbook. We select all the software companies purchased by
Facebook and Google for more than $500M. There are 9 acquisitions that satisfies these criteria:
7 by Google and 2 by Facebook. We list them in Table 1.
With traditional technologies it is simple to determine whether a product or service is a
complement or a substitute: a match is a substitute to a lighter because the demand for matches
goes up when you tax lighters. It is a complement to cigarettes because the demand for matches
goes down when you tax cigarettes. With multisided digital platforms, it is more complicated,
because the definition depends upon which side of the platform one looks at. It is easy to classify
both WhatsApp and Instagram as substitute of Facebook, but what about Youtube and Google?
From a consumer perspective, Google search is a complement to Youtube, because customers
need to search for videos before they watch them. Yet, on the advertising side of the business,
Youtube is a substitute because it can provide clients with an alternative way to microtarget ads.
Therefore, we define as a substitute a product or service that can replace either the
customer base or the ad base of a platform, leading to a potential substitution of the existing
platform with a new one. Using this definition, not all the acquisitions are substitute. For
example, AdMob (a company that offered advertising solutions for several mobile platforms)
and Doubleclick (a company that displayed and tracked banner ads across a network of websites)
are complements, since they enhance the ad experience of existing platforms, but – by
themselves—cannot replace any of the platform. The same can be said for Postini and Apigee.
Postini was an e-mail, Web security, and archiving service, very useful to enhance the
functioning of Gmail, but not able by itselfto replace email. Apigee was an API management
and predictive analytics software provider, again very useful to the Google experience but not a
potential substitute for any business of Google.
The distinction between complement a substitute is further complicated by the multi-
market nature of these platforms, especially Google. Google does not only offer search services,
but also email services (Gmail), navigation services (Google map), and traveling services
(Google Trips). More importantly, these services do not operate as independent units of a
conglomerate, but they are integrated (at least from a data collection point of view) to offer
advertisers the best possible experience. Thus, it is easy to classify Waze, a navigation software,
as a substitute, because it directly competes with Google Map. For the same reason, we should
classify “ITA software” (an airfare search and pricing system) as a substitute. While it is difficult
24
to imagine that in 2010 ITA software could replace Google as an overall search engine, it was
competing head-to-head with Google in an important segment of the search market, i.e.,
travelling. The last column of Table 1 summarizes our classification of the major acquisitions of
the two digital platforms.
Pitchbook classifies venture capital financing according to two criteria: 1) Financing Stage,
which classifies the stage of development at which a firm is financed (Accelerator/Incubator,
Seed, Angel, Early Stage, Later Stage; 2) Financing Rounds, which track the sequential order of
external financing. For most of our analysis we focus on early stages (from Accelerator-
Incubator to Early Stage). Only when we want to focus on new entry will we limit our attention
to Round 1. For these deals we collect the total dollar amount invested by venture capital
companies in start-up companies operating in the same “space” as the company acquired and the
number of VC deals funded.
We determine whether a start-up belongs to the same space as the acquired company (and is
thus “treated”) based on two metrics. The first metric relies on a text-based measure of similarity
produced by Pitchbook. Similar to Hoberg and Phillips (2016), Pitchbook applies a machine-
learning algorithm to companies’ business descriptions to measure their degree of similarity.
10
In Table 2, we experiment with different thresholds of similarity between 75% and 85%.
The second measure classifies companies as “treated” if they belong to the same primary
industry and operate in the same industry verticals as the acquired company. The primary
industry, according to Pitchbook, is the industry subgroup in which the company primarily
operates. The industry vertical is a specific element of the company which isn’t accurately
captured by industry focus. Verticals are useful in identifying companies that offer niche
products. For example, WhatsApp belongs to the primary industry Communication Software,
which is one of the sixteen subgroups in the industry group Software, which in turn is one of the
six industry groups in the sector Information Technology. Further, WhatsApp belongs to the
mobile sector vertical.
We collect these data on similar companies for 7 observation years for each acquisition – the
3 years before the acquisition year + the acquisition year + the 3 years after. As Table 2 shows,
there is a trade-off between narrowing the definition of similarity and reducing the number of
10
https://techcrunch.com/2018/06/19/pitchbook-now-offers-users-suggested-companies-when-they-search/.
25
“treatedearly stage companies. If we use a threshold of 85%, we lose 14% of the observations
and one quarter of the remaining observations is based on a set of less than 5 companies. If we
increase the limit to 90%, we lose almost a third of the sample and for half of the remaining ones
we have at most four companies as a comparison set. By contrast, if we lower this threshold to
75%, the treated group consists of up to 480 companies, possibly increasing the noise. For this
reason, we start with an initial threshold of 80% similarity. With this threshold, we have no
treated company in only three observation years, which we drop from the sample.
Table 2 reports the summary statistics of the relative level of investments and deals, using
both measures of “treated” companies and normalizing by the early VC deals in the software
industry (see below).
3. Empirical Results
3.1 Main Results
In Figure 1, we plot the raw number of new venture capital deals and the dollar amount invested
in new deals in the social media space. The number of deals peaks in 2014, the year of Facebook
acquisition of WhatsApp, and the amount peaks shortly after, in 2016. While these pictures are
broadly consistent with the idea that VC funds shy away from social media after the
consolidation of the power of Facebook, they are certainly not conclusive. The decline over time
can be driven by many other factors. To try to control for these other factors, in all the following
analyses we will deflate all the numbers by the overall performance of VC investment in the
software sector during the same years.
Figure 2a plots the relative investment in treated companies, around an acquisition event.
For each event we identify as treated the companies in the same “space” (defined as in Section 2)
of the company acquired. For each of the 63 observation years [= (3 years before+ acquisition
year + 3 years after)*9 acquisitions], we sum the investment across treated companies. To adjust
for cyclicality, this sum is deflated by the total investment made that year by venture capitalists
in the software sector. This ratio is expressed in percentage terms. Then, we average these ratios
across the nine events using event time, as it is commonly done in event studies. As we can see
from the graph, when we use as a measure of similarity the Pitchbook-based text measure, where
the threshold is set at 80%, the relative level of investment drops from 2.6% to 1.5% (a 40%
drop) in the three years following an acquisition.
26
While the paucity of observations makes it difficult to talk about statistical significance, in
Table 3 we present the same results in regression format. The dummy variable post-acquisition
equals to 1 in the three years after the acquisition. In columns 1- 2, the left hand side variable is
the standardized level of investment, computed as described above. As column 1 shows, the
dummy variable post-acquisition has a negative and statistically significant coefficient. Relative
investments drop by 0.98 percentage points. Given the average is 2.1 (see Table 2), this
corresponds to a 46% drop in the three years after an acquisition. In column 3 we repeat
specification 1 inserting a fixed effect for every acquisition. Thus, column 2 focuses on the time
series variation of the sample of treated companies for each acquisition. The coefficient is
identical to the one estimated in column 1, suggesting that the effect identified in specification 1
is not spurious.
Figure 1b plots the number of deals in event time, normalized by the number of early stage
deals in all the software industry (multiplied by 100). Similar to relative investments, we
observe a 43% decline in the relative number of deals: from 2.2% the three years before an
acquisition to 1.3% three years later. The pre-trend decline in the relative number of deals is not
surprising. In early stages, the VC investment rounds are more frequent (Gompers, 1995). As
firms mature, rounds become less frequent: hence a decline in the sheer number of deals. The
pre-event decline, however, accelerates substantially after an acquisition, as Figure1b shows.
Columns 3 to 4 of Table 3a analyze these patterns in a regression framework. In both
columns the dependent variable is the same relative number of deals used in Figure1b. In column
3, it is regressed just on the post-acquisition dummy variable. The coefficient is negative and
statistically significant. After an acquisition the relative number of deals drops by 0.85
percentage points. Given that the sample average is 1.7 (see Table 2), this corresponds to a 50%
drop. The effect is identical if we include the acquisition year in the post-acquisition dummy
(column 4).
Table 3b repeats the same analysis with the industry-based measure of similarity. In column
1 we see that there is a drop in investments, equal to 1 percentage points, although this drop is
not statistically different from zero. Since the sample average is 2.5%, this corresponds to a 36%
drop. Introducing a fixed effect for each of the nine acquisitions (column 2) does not change the
coefficient, but it makes it statistically different from zero at the 5% level.
27
In columns 3 and 4, the dependent variable is the relative number of deals. After an
acquisition, it drops by 0.8 percentage points, equal to a 32% drop (column 3). The effect is
similar if we include a fixed effect for each of the nine acquisitions (columns 4).
In sum, regardless of the measure of similarity used, we observe that companies similar to
the ones acquired experienced a significant drop in investments and number of financing deals
after the acquisition by Facebook or Google.
Table 3c compares the effect of acquisitions on relative investments when we change the
threshold of similarity in the Pitchbook measure. No matter what the threshold is the estimated
effect of an acquisition is negative and statistically significant, in spite of the decline number of
observations. The magnitude of the coefficient drops, but so does the average of the relative
investment in the sample (see Table 2). When we take this fact into consideration, the percentage
decline increases in magnitude from -43% to -67%.
3.2 Robustness
An alternative explanation of these results is that most of the start-ups very similar to the one
acquired by Google or Facebook were created with the hope of being acquired by Google or
Facebook. Thus, when the two tech giants chose a specific target, the potential alternatives lose
financing.
11
To address this concern further, we selected as a treated group a set of start-ups that
are similar to the acquired ones, but not too similar. From a practical point of view, we look at
investments and number of deals of start-ups that have a Pitchbook measure of similarity
between 75% and 85%. The results in Table 4 are similar to the ones in Table 3. There is a
quantitatively large drop in investments and deals after an acquisition.
Even if acquisitions deter new investments, a VC firms might find it optimal to continue
financing its existing start-ups, because most of the investments is already sunk and suspending
any additional financing might imply a total loss. Yet, the same logic does not apply for the
totally new investments. For this reason, in Table 5 we repeat the same analysis of Table 3
restricting our attention to first round investments only. As in Table 3, acquisitions have a
negative and statistically significant impact on the number of dollar invested in new start-ups and
11
A more sinister explanation (more consistent with the one we propose) is that the acquisition augmented Google
or Facebook is an even more indomitable competitor for future entrants. Regardless, it is heartening for our model
that the effects are large across a wide range of possible entrants.
28
on the number of new start-up financed. As expected, the impact is quantitatively larger: -51% in
the case of dollar amount and -46% in the case of number of start-ups.
3.3 Complements and Substitutes
In Table 6 we split the sample based on our classification of complements and substitutes (see
Table 1). The pattern of results is similar in both subsamples. While the drop in relative
investments seem similar for complements and substitutes, this is not true in relative terms. As
Table 2 shows, the average level of investments in substitutes before an acquisition is 0.5, thus
there is a 76% drop, versus the 34% drop experienced by complements (which have a pre-
acquisition level of 1.2.
4. Policy implications and Extensions
4.1 Anti-Trust Policy
It is not straightforward to go from our findings to policy. In our model, allowing incumbent
platforms to acquire new entrants enhances ex-post efficiency, but may reduce the ex-ante
incentives to innovate. Thus, the overall welfare implications of allowing mergers depend on the
relative importance of ex-ante underinvestment vis-à-vis ex-post inefficiency.
A case-by-case approach will inevitably lead to the anti-trust authorities approving all
acquisitions, because ex-post efficiency considerations would prevail (at that point the
investments are sunk and in a case-by-case approach current decisions will not bind future ones).
A blunt non-contingent rule (e.g., no large acquisitions by main incumbent platforms will be
allowed) will provide greater predictability of outcomes, stimulating greater innovation; but it
can be very costly, because it prevents the industry from realizing ex post efficiencies. For this
reason, it is preferable to consider other possibilities. The advantage of modeling the key
frictions is that the model can suggest alternative fixes.
4.2 Interoperability
A crucial friction in our model is the cost of switching. In the model we assumed this cost to be
an exogenous parameter. Yet, companies can affect this switching cost and they generally prefer
to increase it, so as to increase their market power. The regulatory authorities can affect
29
switching costs too. A simple way to reduce switching costs is to mandate a common standard.
For example, all plugs in America are the same, making it easier to connect our appliances. In
the same way, the internet access protocols are standard, allowing a world wide web.
In a similar way, we assume the existence of network externalities associated with
belonging to specific networks. Such network externalities, however, are not just an inevitable
consequence of a technology, but a combination of technology and standards. In the early phone
industry, there were enormous network externalities because one could only call people on the
same network. When the U.S. government mandated interoperability among the various phone-
service providers, network externalities associated with specific networks disappeared. The same
can be done for social media. If the government mandates a common Application Program
Interface (API), it is easier for intermediaries to connect customers participating on different
social media. So, both the switching costs and the network externalities are greatly reduced.
12
Recall that a key friction in our model is the presence of network externalities associated
with each competitor’s network. When everyone can get access to the externalities associated
with the whole network, there is no distortion in the incentive to innovate because the better
product will always prevail. Thus, by forcing interoperability, the regulatory authorities can
restore the proper incentive to innovate.
4.3. Data Ownership
We have assumed no constraints on the entrant’s ability to innovate. In the digital world,
past customer-generated data are crucial to fine tune new products offered to consumers. Thus,
incumbent-collected data on the customer represents an important barrier to entry for newcomers
effectively lowers the distribution of
θ
for any investment
E
C
. The greater access to customer
data entrants have, the more they can fine-tune their products, leveling the playing field with the
incumbent. Thus, default allocation of data ownership is crucial in spurring competition and
innovation. Rules that allow incumbent platforms free use of their accumulated data make it
easier for incumbent to exploit their network externalities in different lines of business. If a
platform, for example, can freely use its customer information to market a new cryptocurrency, it
12
Alternatively, customer experience across platforms could be standardized, minimizing switching costs. Techies,
however, may want to go beyond the ordinary customer experience into the details of every feature. These may be
harder to standardize. Furthermore, the incumbent may gain an advantage here, since she participates in setting the
standards, and they will be best suited to the features she has.
30
can easily gain a head start vis-à-vis any other cryptocurrency. Thus, the incentives to innovate
in any area where an existing platform can expand are curtailed by the possibility that the
platform might enter with a data advantage.
The new European data protection rule – also known as GDPR – limits the use of these
data by incumbents, unless they have asked explicit authorization from the customers. In so
doing, it reduces the incumbent’s advantage somewhat, promoting innovation. Of course, it also
means that entrants will have to ask each customer for permission to use their data, increasing
their costs of fine-tuning also. There have also been proposals to allow customers to own their
data, and sell it to whomsoever they desire (see Lanier (2013), Posner and Weyl (2018)). This
would level the playing field, provided data collectors are compensated for their cost of
collection, and data intermediaries arise to facilitate storage and sales.
4.4. Patent Protection
In a similar vein, it follows that the more an incumbent can freely copy the technological
innovations of new entrants, the worse the incentives of early adopters to switch to a new entrant
will be, and thus the lower the incentives to innovate will be. This feature is not unique to our
model. Even in a neoclassical model of competitive innovation, lack of protection of innovation
will curtail innovation incentives. In our model, however, the effect is much stronger. In the
traditional duopoly setting, if the incumbent perfectly imitates the innovation of the new entrant
and it sells it at the same price, the new entrant still can sell its product. In our model, if the
incumbent perfectly imitates the new features of the entrant, the new entrant will not be able to
attract customers because the incumbent’s network externalities will dominate. Thus, in the
absence of any patent protection, the incentives to enter with a superior product will be severely
curtailed.
Note, however, that a very strong patent protection system can be a double-edged sword,
because it protects incumbentsproperty rights too, possibly creating an insurmountable
advantage over potential entrants (see Bryan and Hovenkamp (2019)). To properly derive the
optimal degree of patent protection, we would need to model the incumbent’s incentives to
innovate. This is outside the scope of this paper.
31
4.5. Keeping out Foreign Incumbents
The possibly adverse effects of incumbent platforms acquisition on innovation and entry
may perhaps also be gleaned from the history of digital platforms in the United States, China,
and the EU. The EU, which has a market as large as the United States, did not produce its own
home-grown giants. By contrast, China, which has blocked the acquisition and entry of foreign
platforms, has created an ecosystem of platforms (from Ali Baba to Baidu and Tencent) that
rivals those in the United States. A possible explanation, consistent with our model, is that EU
entrants had to contend from the beginning with US incumbents, who built extensive networks in
Europe early on. By contrast, Chinese entrants did not have the same problem.
In the future, India might provide an interesting testing ground. Initially, India had
allowed relatively free entry to foreign platforms. Recently, however, it has introduced a new set
of rules hamstringing the dominant incumbent market places, Amazon and Flipkart (owned by
Walmart), with the intent of creating more incentives for domestic entrants. Only time will tell if
this approach is successful in growing domestic champions.
The above argument is nothing more than a variant of the standard argument for
protection of “infant” industries proposed by Alexander Hamilton and developed by Friedrich
List. As in Section 4.4, network externalities just make the case much stronger. In addition, our
model suggests that the infant” industry protection argument can be used not just in new
industries, but also in developed ones, like the software industry in the United States. Of course,
all the traditional caveats associated with the infant industry argument still pertain here.
5. Conclusions
Venture capitalists talk about a “kill zone” created by acquisitions, such as those by Facebook
and Google, in the start-up space. This idea seems at odds not only with standard textbook
economics, but with logic itself. Why should the prospect of being acquired at hefty multiples
discourage new entry?
In this paper we construct a simple model that rationalizes this result. In the presence of
network externalities, early adopters generate an important externality: they facilitate the
adoption by less sophisticated customers, helping the market converge to the platform with the
superior technology. These early adopters, however, face significant switching costs, thus they
will switch only if the benefit of switching is reasonable large. This benefit is given by the
32
product of the technological difference and the time this difference will persist. Since a merger
immediately transmits the superior technology to everybody, it reduces the payoff to early
adoption. The prospect of mergers then reduces switching, makes it harder for entrants to acquire
customers and offer network externalities for any given technological superiority, and thus
reduces the price at which they can be acquired. This then reduces their incentive to innovate.
We test this prediction using data on investment in startups. We show that VCs
significantly reduce the number of deals and the amount of money they invest in markets near
one where Facebook and Google have made a large acquisition, after the two giant digital
platforms have made those acquisitions. While an outright prohibition of acquisitions may
reduce welfare, the model provides alternative welfare-improving forms of intervention.
The most important message, though, is a simple one: it is dangerous to apply twentieth
century economic intuitions to twenty first century economic problems. Our paper suggests one
reason why.
33
References
Aghion, P., Bloom, N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., and Howitt, P. “Competition and Innovation:
An Inverted-U Relationship.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 120 (2005), pp. 701–728.
Bourreau, Marc, 2019, “Digital Conglomerates and EU Competition Policy”, 2019, Working
Paper Telecom ParisTech, CERRE Alexandre de Streel, University of Namur, CRIDS/NADI,
CERRE
Cabral, Luis M. B., 2018, Standing on the Shoulders of Dwarfs: Dominant Firms and Innovation
Incentives. CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP13115.
Cunningham, Colleeen, Song Ma and Florian Ederer, “Killer Acquisitions”, 2019, Academy of
Management Proceedings, Vol. 2018, No. 1, Published Online:9 Jul 2018,
https://doi.org/10.5465/AMBPP.2018.301
Hylton, Keith, “Digital Platforms And Antitrust Law”, 2019, Working Paper, Boston University
School of Law.
Hyun Shin and Stephen Morris, “Rethinking multiple equilibria in macroeconomic modelling"
NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 2000, pp 139-61
Hyun Shin and Stephen Morris, “Global games: theory and applications", 2003, in M
Dewatripont, L Hansen and S Turnovsky (eds), Advances in economics and econometrics, the
Eighth World Congress, Cambridge University Press.
Khan, Lina, “Amazon’s Anti-Trust Paradox”, Yale Law Journal, 2017.
Khan, Lina, “The Separation Of Platforms And CommerceColumbia Law Review , Vol. 119,
No. 4 (MAY 2019), pp. 973-1098.
Lanier, Jaron, Who Owns the Future? (New York: Simon and Schuster, 2013
Li, J. and W. Mann, “Initial Coin Offering and Platform Building,” mimeo, UCLA, 2019.
Phillips, Gordon, Alexei Zhdanov, R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition
Activity, The Review of Financial Studies, Volume 26, Issue 1, January 2013, Pages 34–
78, https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhs109
Posner, Eric and Glen Weyl, Radical Markets: Uprooting Capitalism and Democracy for a Just
Society, Princeton University Press, Princeton, 2018.
Schumpeter, J., The Theory of Economic Development. New York: Harper, 1934.
Schumpeter, J., Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University
Press, 1942.
34
Segal, I. and M. Whinston (2007), “Antitrust in Innovative Industries,” American Economic
Review, 97 (5), pp. 1703-1730.
Seru, Amit, 2014 “Firm boundaries matter: Evidence from conglomerates and R&D activity”,
2014, Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 111, issue 2, 381-405
Stone, Brad, The Everything Store: Jeff Bezos and the Age of Amazon Little, Brown, and
Company, New York, 2013.
Wen Wen and Feng Zhu, “Threat of platform‐owner entry and complementor responses:
Evidence from the mobile app market”, 2019, Strategic Management Journal, Volume 40, Issue
9, p 1336-1367.
Wu, Timothy, 2018, “Blind Spot: The Attention Economy and the Law”, working paper,
Columbia Law School.
35
Figure 1: Number of VC Deals in the Social Media Space
Figure 1a plots the number of new start-ups financed for the first time by a venture capitalist in the social media
space. Figure 1b the actual dollar amount of funding going to first-time financing of start-ups in the social media
space. Both data series are from Pitchbook.
a: Number of Deals
b: Dollar amount financed (in million $)
0
500
1000
1500
2000
2500
2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019
0
500
1000
1500
2000
2500
3000
3500
2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019
36
Figure 2: Effect of Acquisitions on Amount of Investments and Number of Deals
Figure 2a plots the average early stage VC investment rate in companies similar to the one acquired. To adjust for
cyclicality, the level of investments is divided by all VC investments in early deals in the software industry made in
the same year. This ratio is expressed in percentage terms. The relative investment corresponding to each
acquisition-year is then averaged across the nine events using event time. Figure 1b plots the relative number of
early deals in event time, normalized by the total number of early deals in all the software industry (multiplied by
100). Source: Pitchbook
Figure 2a: Relative Investment Before and After an Acquisition
Figure 2b: Relative Number of Deals Before and After an Acquisition
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3
0.00
0.50
1.00
1.50
2.00
2.50
3.00
-3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3
37
Table 1. Acquisitions Considered
All software companies acquired by Facebook or Google for more than 500 M between the
beginning of 2006 and the end of 2018. Source: Pitchbook
Complementarity
Price
paid
in $M
Year
Acquirer
Target
Software Sector
2006
Google
Youtube
1,650
Multimedia and Design
Substitute
2007
Google
DoubleClick
3,100
Internet
Complement
2009
Google
AdMob
750
Vertical Market
Complement
2009
Google
Postini
625
Network Management
Complement
2011
Google
ITA
Software
676
Vertical Market
Substitute
2012
Facebook
Instagram
1,000
Social Platform
Substitute
2013
Google
Waze
966
Communication
Substitute
2014
Facebook
WhatsApp
19,000
Communication
Substitute
2016
Google
Apigee
625
Development
Applications
Complement
38
Table 2. Summary Statistics
For each of the 9 acquisitions listed in Table 1, we collect data for a 7 year-window centered on the acquisition year.
The investment relative to VC investments is the ratio of the amount of VC investments in companies similar to the
one acquired divided by the amount of VC investments in the software industry in the same year. This ratio is
expressed in percentage terms. The number of deals relative to total VC deals is the ratio of VC deals in companies
similar to the one acquired divided by the number of VC deals in the software industry in the same year. This ratio is
expressed in percentage terms. Number of comparison companies is the number of similar companies in each
acquisition. In (a), we consider as similar the companies that have the same sector and vertical industry as the
acquired company. In (b), (c), (d), (e) we consider companies as similar if they have a Pitchbook measure of
similarity above 75%, 80%, 85%, and 90% respectively. In (f ), we consider companies as similar if they have a
measure of similarity between 75% and 85%. In (g) we look only at the first round of financing. In (h) we divide the
acquisitions into complements and substitutes (see Table 1).
39
Variable Mean St Dev Min 25th 50th 75th Max Obs
Similarity based on sector and vertical
Investment relative to total VC investments 2.9 2.8 0.1 0.6 2.2 4.2 12.9 63
Number of deals relative to total VC deal 2.5 2.0 0.1 0.7 2.2 3.7 7.8 63
Number of comparison companies 93.1 119.7 2 19 36 131 480 63
Similarity based on Pitchbook index >75
Investment relative to total VC investments 4.5 4.2 0.0 1.9 2.9 7.2 20.6 63
Number of deals relative to total VC deal 4.1 3.8 0.0 1.8 2.4 6.7 17.7 63
Number of comparison companies 153.7 169.2 1 36 98 213 746 63
Similarity based on Pitchbook index >80
Investment relative to total VC investments 2.1 1.9 0.0 0.7 1.9 2.8 10.5 60
Number of deals relative to total VC deal 1.7 1.5 0.0 0.6 1.5 2.3 8.4 60
Number of comparison companies 72.0 79.8 1 19 34 84.5 282 60
Similarity based on Pitchbook index >85
Investment relative to total VC investments 0.9 0.8 0.0 0.3 0.8 1.3 4.4 54
Number of deals relative to total VC deal 0.6 0.5 0.0 0.2 0.5 0.8 2.6 54
Number of comparison companies 28.2 37.4 1 5 10.5 35 121 54
Similarity based on Pitchbook index >90
Investment relative to total VC investments 0.6 0.8 0.0 0.1 0.3 0.7 4.1 43
Number of deals relative to total VC deal 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.5 43
Number of comparison companies 10.5 12.0 1 1 4 18 41 43
Similarity based on Pitchbook index >75 & <85
Investment relative to total VC investments 4.3 4.0 0.0 1.5 2.5 6.6 18.1 54
Number of deals relative to total VC deal 4.1 3.5 0.2 1.5 2.3 7.0 15.2 54
Number of comparison companies 28.2 37.4 1 5 10.5 35 121 54
Investment relative to total VC investments 0.8 0.7 0.0 0.2 0.8 1.1 4.2 58
Number of deals relative to total VC deal 1.2 0.9 0.0 0.4 1.1 1.5 4.2 58
Number of comparison companies 56.9 65.2 1 11 26 69 235 58
Investment relative to total VC investments 0.5 0.4 0.0 0.1 0.4 0.9 1.5 30
Number of deals relative to total VC deal 0.9 0.9 0.0 0.3 0.5 1.3 3.0 30
Number of comparison companies 60.8 72.4 1 5 32 69 235 30
Complements
Investment relative to total VC investments 1.2 0.8 0.1 0.8 1.0 1.5 4.2 28
Number of deals relative to total VC deal 1.5 0.9 0.2 0.9 1.4 1.7 4.2 28
Number of comparison companies 52.6 57.4 10 16 22 81.5 167 28
Substitute
New Deals
40
Table 3. Post Acquisition Decline in Investments and Deals
The dependent variable in the first four columns is the amount of VC investments in companies similar to the
acquired one divided by all VC investments in early-stage deals in the same industry. The dependent variable in the
last four columns is the number of VC deals in companies similar to the acquired one divided by all VC early-stage
deals in the same industry. In Panel A, a start-up is considered similar to the acquired company if it has a Pitchbook
measure of similarity with the acquired company above 80%. In Panel B it is considered similar if it shares the
same sector and vertical industry. In Panel C we alter the threshold of similarity between 75% and 85%. Post
acquisition is a dummy variable equal to 1 in the 3 years after the acquisition. t statistics in parentheses, * p<0.10, **
p<0.05, and *** p<0.01.
Panel A: Pitchbook-based measure of similarity
Panel B: Industry-based measure of similarity
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Post acquisition dummy -0.967** -0.927*** -0.845** -0.813***
(-2.22) (-3.06) (-2.44) (-3.96)
Constant 2.521*** 2.504*** 2.088*** 2.074***
(6.61)
(11.04) (6.76) (13.81)
Acquisition fixed effects No Yes No Yes
N 60 60
60 60
R^2
0.067
0.646 0.079 0.753
Relative Investment
Relative # of deals
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Post acquisition dummy -1.044 -1.044** -0.812* -0.812***
(-1.60) (-2.58) (-1.69) (-3.07)
Constant 3.397*** 3.397*** 2.830*** 2.830***
(6.35) (11.84) (7.39) (15.75)
Acquisition fixed effects No Yes No Yes
N 63 63 63 63
R^2 0.035 0.706 0.040 0.770
Relative Investment
Relative # of deals
41
Panel C: Robustness to Different Thresholds of Similarity
Pitchbook measure of similarity> 75% 80% 85% 90%
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Post acquisition dummy -1.947* -1.947*** -0.967** -0.927*** -0.592*** -0.565*** -0.402* -0.436**
(-1.99) (-3.86) (-2.22) (-3.06) (-3.01) (-3.05) (-1.96) (-2.10)
Constant 5.357*** 5.357*** 2.521*** 2.504*** 1.158*** 1.146*** 0.722*** 0.736***
(6.38) (15.19) (6.61) (11.04) (6.82) (7.75) (4.00) (4.26)
Acquisition fixed effects No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes
N 63 60 60 60 54 54 43 43
R^2 0.052 0.067 0.067 0.646 0.133 0.347 0.070 0.275
Relative Investment
42
Table 4. Restricting the Sample to Start-Ups not Too Similar
The dependent variable in the first four columns is the amount of VC investments in companies similar to the
acquired one divided by all VC investments in early-stage deals in the same industry. The dependent variable in the
last four columns is the number of VC deals in companies similar to the acquired one divided by all VC early-stage
deals in the same industry. A start-up is considered similar to the acquired company if it has a Pitchbook measure of
similarity with the acquired company between 75% and 85%. Post acquisition is a dummy variable equal to 1 in the
3 years after the acquisition. t statistics in parentheses, * p<0.10, ** p<0.05, and *** p<0.01.
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Post acquisition dummy -1.914*
-1.748*** -1.727*
-1.563***
(-1.91) (-3.69) (-1.92)
(-4.76)
Constant 5.176*** 5.103***
4.903*** 4.830***
(6.01) (14.16)
(6.56)
(19.87)
Acquisition fixed effects No Yes
No Yes
N
54 54 54 54
R^2 0.058 0.828 0.060
0.897
Relative Investment
Relative # of Deals
43
Table 5. New Deals
The dependent variable in the first two columns is the amount of VC investment in first financing deals in
companies similar to the one acquired, divided by the amount invested in all new early-stage deals. The dependent
variable in the last two columns is the number of VC investments in first financing deals in companies similar to the
one acquired, divided by the number of all VC early-stage deals. A start-up is considered similar to the acquired
company if it has a Pitchbook measure of similarity with the acquired company greater than 80 %. Post acquisition
is a dummy variable equal to 1 in the 3 years after the acquisition. t statistics in parentheses, * p<0.10, ** p<0.05,
and *** p<0.01.
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Post acquisition dummy -0.418** -0.376*** -0.601*** -0.534***
(-2.42) (-3.34) (-2.77) (-4.67)
Constant 0.997*** 0.978*** 1.445*** 1.415***
(7.04) (10.35) (7.85) (15.88)
Acquisition fixed effects No Yes No Yes
N 58 58 58 58
R^2 0.087 0.658 0.110 0.797
44
Table 6. Substitute and Complements
This Table replicates Table 5, splitting the sample between acquisitions of substitutes and complements, as classified
in Table 1. The dependent variable in the first two columns is the amount of VC investment in first financing deals
in companies similar to the one acquired, divided by the amount invested in all new early-stage deals. The
dependent variable in the last two columns is the number of VC investments in first financing deals in companies
similar to the one acquired, divided by the number of all VC early-stage deals. A start-up is considered similar to the
acquired company if it has a Pitchbook measure of similarity with the acquired company above 80%. Post
acquisition is a dummy variable equal to 1 in the 3 years after the acquisition. t statistics in parentheses, * p<0.10, **
p<0.05, and *** p<0.01.
(1) (2)
(3) (4)
(5)
(6) (7) (8)
Post acquisition dummy -0.378** -0.350*** -0.404 -0.404* -0.461 -0.372*** -0.708** -0.708***
(-2.67) (-3.92) (-1.54) (-1.89) (-1.50) (-3.03) (-2.58) (-3.68)
Constant 0.642*** 0.628*** 1.352*** 1.352*** 1.103*** 1.061*** 1.787*** 1.787***
(5.23) (8.80) (5.97) (7.58) (4.30) (12.80) (7.36) (11.35)
Acquisition fixed effects No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes
N 30 30 0.072 0.468 30 30 28 28
R^2 0.191 0.741 0.072 0.468 0.070 0.887 0.175 0.661
Complements
Relative Investment
Relative # of Deals
Substitute
Complements
Substitute